Competitive equilibrium (also called: Walrasian equilibrium) is a concept of
economic equilibrium
In economics, economic equilibrium is a situation in which the economic forces of supply and demand are balanced, meaning that economic variables will no longer change.
Market equilibrium in this case is a condition where a market price is es ...
, introduced by
Kenneth Arrow
Kenneth Joseph Arrow (August 23, 1921 – February 21, 2017) was an American economist, mathematician and political theorist. He received the John Bates Clark Medal in 1957, and the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences in 1972, along with ...
and
Gérard Debreu
Gérard Debreu (; 4 July 1921 – 31 December 2004) was a French-born economist and mathematician. Best known as a professor of economics at the University of California, Berkeley, where he began work in 1962, he won the 1983 Nobel Memorial Prize ...
in 1951, appropriate for the analysis of
commodity market
A commodity market is a market that trades in the primary economic sector rather than manufactured products. The primary sector includes agricultural products, energy products, and metals. Soft commodities may be perishable and harvested, w ...
s with flexible prices and many traders, and serving as the benchmark of
efficiency
Efficiency is the often measurable ability to avoid making mistakes or wasting materials, energy, efforts, money, and time while performing a task. In a more general sense, it is the ability to do things well, successfully, and without waste.
...
in economic analysis. It relies crucially on the assumption of a
competitive environment where each trader decides upon a quantity that is so small compared to the total quantity traded in the market that their individual transactions have no influence on the prices. Competitive markets are an ideal standard by which other market structures are evaluated.
Definitions
A competitive equilibrium (CE) consists of two elements:
* A price function
. It takes as argument a vector representing a bundle of commodities, and returns a positive real number that represents its price. Usually the price function is linear - it is represented as a vector of prices, a price for each commodity type.
* An allocation matrix
. For every
,
is the vector of commodities allotted to agent
.
These elements should satisfy the following requirement:
* Satisfaction (market-envy-freeness): Every agent weakly prefers his bundle to any other affordable bundle:
::
, if
then
.
Often, there is an initial endowment matrix
: for every
,
is the initial endowment of agent
. Then, a CE should satisfy some additional requirements:
* Market Clearance: the demand equals the supply, no items are created or destroyed:
::
.
* Individual Rationality: all agents are better-off after the trade than before the trade:
::
.
* Budget Balance: all agents can afford their allocation given their endowment:
::
.
Definition 2
This definition explicitly allows for the possibility that there may be multiple commodity arrays that are equally appealing. Also for zero prices. An alternative definition
[ relies on the concept of a ''demand-set''. Given a price function P and an agent with a utility function U, a certain bundle of goods x is in the demand-set of the agent if: for every other bundle y. A ''competitive equilibrium'' is a price function P and an allocation matrix X such that:
* The bundle allocated by X to each agent is in that agent's demand-set for the price-vector P;
* Every good which has a positive price is fully allocated (i.e. every unallocated item has price 0).
]
Approximate equilibrium
In some cases it is useful to define an equilibrium in which the rationality condition is relaxed.[ Given a positive value (measured in monetary units, e.g., dollars), a price vector and a bundle , define as a price vector in which all items in x have the same price they have in P, and all items not in x are priced more than their price in P.
In a ''-competitive-equilibrium'', the bundle x allocated to an agent should be in that agent's demand-set for the ''modified'' price vector, .
This approximation is realistic when there are buy/sell commissions. For example, suppose that an agent has to pay dollars for buying a unit of an item, in addition to that item's price. That agent will keep his current bundle as long as it is in the demand-set for price vector . This makes the equilibrium more stable.
]
Examples
The following examples involve an exchange economy with two agents, Jane and Kelvin, two goods
In economics, goods are anything that is good, usually in the sense that it provides welfare or utility to someone. Alan V. Deardorff, 2006. ''Terms Of Trade: Glossary of International Economics'', World Scientific. Online version: Deardorffs ...
e.g. bananas (x) and apples (y), and no money.
1. Graphical example: Suppose that the initial allocation is at point X, where Jane has more apples than Kelvin does and Kelvin has more bananas than Jane does.
By looking at their indifference curve
In economics, an indifference curve connects points on a graph representing different quantities of two goods, points between which a consumer is ''indifferent''. That is, any combinations of two products indicated by the curve will provide the c ...
s of Jane and of Kelvin, we can see that this is not an equilibrium - both agents are willing to trade with each other at the prices and . After trading, both Jane and Kelvin move to an indifference curve which depicts a higher level of utility, and . The new indifference curves intersect at point E. The slope of the tangent of both curves equals -.
And the ;
.
The marginal rate of substitution
In economics, the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) is the rate at which a consumer can give up some amount of one good in exchange for another good while maintaining the same level of utility. At equilibrium consumption levels (assuming no ext ...
(MRS) of Jane equals that of Kelvin. Therefore, the 2 individuals society reaches Pareto efficiency
In welfare economics, a Pareto improvement formalizes the idea of an outcome being "better in every possible way". A change is called a Pareto improvement if it leaves at least one person in society better off without leaving anyone else worse ...
, where there is no way to make Jane or Kelvin better off without making the other worse off.
2. Arithmetic example: suppose that both agents have Cobb–Douglas utilities:
:
:
where are constants.
Suppose the initial endowment is