HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

Bayesian-optimal pricing (BO pricing) is a kind of
algorithmic pricing Algorithmic pricing is the practice of automatically setting the requested price for items for sale, in order to maximize the seller's profits. Dynamic pricing algorithms usually rely on one or more of the following data. * Probabilistic and stati ...
in which a seller determines the sell-prices based on probabilistic assumptions on the valuations of the buyers. It is a simple kind of a
Bayesian-optimal mechanism A Bayesian-optimal mechanism (BOM) is a mechanism in which the designer does not know the valuations of the agents for whom the mechanism is designed, but the designer knows that they are random variables and knows the probability distribution of th ...
, in which the price is determined in advance without collecting actual buyers' bids.


Single item and single buyer

In the simplest setting, the seller has a single item to sell (with zero cost), and there is a single potential buyer. The highest price that the buyer is willing to pay for the item is called the ''valuation'' of the buyer. The seller would like to set the price exactly at the buyer's valuation. Unfortunately, the seller does not know the buyer's valuation. In the Bayesian model, it is assumed that the buyer's valuation is a
random variable A random variable (also called random quantity, aleatory variable, or stochastic variable) is a mathematical formalization of a quantity or object which depends on random events. It is a mapping or a function from possible outcomes (e.g., the po ...
drawn from a known probability distribution. Suppose the
cumulative distribution function In probability theory and statistics, the cumulative distribution function (CDF) of a real-valued random variable X, or just distribution function of X, evaluated at x, is the probability that X will take a value less than or equal to x. Ev ...
of the buyer is F(v), defined as the probability that the seller's valuation is less than v. Then, if the price is set to p, the
expected value In probability theory, the expected value (also called expectation, expectancy, mathematical expectation, mean, average, or first moment) is a generalization of the weighted average. Informally, the expected value is the arithmetic mean of a l ...
of the seller's revenue is: :Rev(p) = p\cdot (1-F(p)) because the probability that the buyer will want to buy the item is 1-F(p), and if this happens, the seller's revenue will be p. The seller would like to find the price that maximizes Rev(p). The first-order condition, that the optimal price p^* should satisfy, is: :p^* = where f(p)=F'(p)= the
probability density function In probability theory, a probability density function (PDF), or density of a continuous random variable, is a function whose value at any given sample (or point) in the sample space (the set of possible values taken by the random variable) can ...
. For example, if the probability distribution of the buyer's valuation is uniform in ,a+d/math>, then F(v)=(v-a)/d and f(v)=1/d (in ,a+d/math>). The first-order condition is p^* = (a+d-p^*) which implies p^* = (a+d)/2. This is the optimal price only if it is in the range ,a+d/math> (i.e., when a\leq d). Otherwise (when a\geq d), the optimal price is p^* = a. This optimal price has an alternative interpretation: it is the solution to the equation: :w(p^*)=0 where w is the
virtual valuation In auction theory, particularly Bayesian-optimal mechanism design, a virtual valuation of an agent is a function that measures the surplus that can be extracted from that agent. A typical application is a seller who wants to sell an item to a poten ...
of the agent. So in this case, BO pricing is equivalent to the
Bayesian-optimal mechanism A Bayesian-optimal mechanism (BOM) is a mechanism in which the designer does not know the valuations of the agents for whom the mechanism is designed, but the designer knows that they are random variables and knows the probability distribution of th ...
, which is an auction with reserve-price p^*.


Single item and many buyers

In this setting, the seller has a single item to sell (with zero cost), and there are multiple potential buyers whose valuations are a random vector drawn from some known probability distribution. Here, different pricing methods come to mind: * ''Symmetric prices'': the seller sets a single price for the item. If one or more buyers accept this price, then one of them is selected arbitrarily. * '' discriminatory prices'': the seller sets a different price for each buyer. If one or more buyers accept this price, then the buyer who accepted the highest price is selected. Discriminatory pricing can be implemented sequentially by ordering the prices in decreasing order and giving the item to the first buyer who accepts the price offered to him. In the multiple-buyer setting, BO pricing is no longer equivalent to BO auction: in pricing, the seller has to determine the price/s in advance, while in auction, the seller can determine the price based on the agents' bids. The competition between the buyers may enable the auctioneer to raise the price. Hence, in theory, the seller can obtain a higher revenue in an auction. Example. There are two buyers whose valuations are distributed uniformly in the range $100,\$200/math>. * The BO auction is the
Vickrey auction A Vickrey auction or sealed-bid second-price auction (SBSPA) is a type of sealed-bid auction. Bidders submit written bids without knowing the bid of the other people in the auction. The highest bidder wins but the price paid is the second-highest ...
with reserve price $100 (= the inverse-virtual-valuation of 0). Its expected revenue is $133. * The BO discriminatory pricing scheme is to offer one agent a price of $150 and the other agent a price of $100. Its expected revenue is 0.5*150 + 0.5*100 = $125. In practice, however, an auction is more complicated for the buyers since it requires them to declare their valuation in advance. The complexity of the auction process might deter buyers and ultimately lead to loss of revenue. Therefore, it is interesting to compare the optimal pricing revenue to the optimal auction revenue, to see how much revenue the seller loses by using the simpler mechanism.


Buyers with independent and identical valuations

Blumrosen and Holenstein study the special case in which the buyers' valuations are random variables drawn independently from the same probability distribution. They show that, when the distribution of the buyers' valuations has ''bounded support'', BO-pricing and BO-auction converge to the same revenue. The convergence rate is asymptotically the same when discriminatory prices are allowed, and slower by a logarithmic factor when symmetric prices must be used. For example, when the distribution is uniform in ,1and there are n potential buyers: * the revenue of the BO auction (a
Vickrey auction A Vickrey auction or sealed-bid second-price auction (SBSPA) is a type of sealed-bid auction. Bidders submit written bids without knowing the bid of the other people in the auction. The highest bidder wins but the price paid is the second-highest ...
with reserve price determined by the probability distribution) is 1-2/n; * the revenue of BO discriminatory pricing is 1-4/n; * the revenue of BO symmetric pricing is 1-\log(n)/n. In contrast, when the distribution of the buyers' valuations has ''unbounded support'', the BO-pricing and the BO-auction might not converge to the same revenue. E.g., when the cdf is F(x) = 1-1/x^2: * the revenue of the BO auction is .88\sqrt; * the revenue of BO discriminatory pricing is .7\sqrt; * the revenue of BO symmetric pricing is .64\sqrt.


Buyers with independent and different valuations

Chawla and Hartline and Malec and Sivan study the setting in which the buyers' valuations are random variables drawn independently from different probability distributions. Moreover, there are constraints on the set of agents that can be served together (for example: there is a limited number of units). They consider two kinds of discriminatory pricing schemes: * In an order-oblivious pricing mechanism (OPM), the mechanism-designer determines a price for each agent. The agents come in an arbitrary order. The mechanism guarantees are for worst-case (adversarial) order of the agents, determined after the agents' valuations are drawn. * In a sequential pricing mechanism (SPM), the mechanism-designer determines both a price for each agent, and an ordering on the agents. The mechanism loops over the agents in the pre-determined order. If the current agent can be served together with the previously-served agents (according to the constraints), then his personal price is offered to him, and he can either take it or leave it. Their general scheme for calculating the prices is: * For each agent j, calculate the probability q_j with which the BO mechanism (Myerson's mechanism) serves agent j. This can be calculated either analytically or by simulations. * The price for agent j is p_j := F_j^(1-C\cdot q_j), where C is a constant (either 1 or 1/2 or 1/3, depending on the setting). In other words, the price p_j satisfies the following condition: ::Prob he valuation of agent j is at least p_j= C \times Prob he BO mechanism serves agent j If C=1 then the marginal-probability that an agent is served by the SPM is equal to the marginal-probability that it is served by the BO auction.
The approximation factors obtainable by an OPM depend on the structure of the constraints: *
uniform matroid In mathematics, a uniform matroid is a matroid in which the independent sets are exactly the sets containing at most ''r'' elements, for some fixed integer ''r''. An alternative definition is that every permutation of the elements is a symmetry. ...
or
partition matroid In mathematics, a partition matroid or partitional matroid is a matroid that is a direct sum of uniform matroids. It is defined over a base set in which the elements are partitioned into different categories. For each category, there is a ''capaci ...
constraints - 2 (i.e, the revenue of the BO OPM is at least 1/2 the revenue of Myerson's BO auction). *
graphic matroid In the mathematical theory of matroids, a graphic matroid (also called a cycle matroid or polygon matroid) is a matroid whose independent sets are the forests in a given finite undirected graph. The dual matroids of graphic matroids are called co- ...
- 3 * Intersection of two
partition matroid In mathematics, a partition matroid or partitional matroid is a matroid that is a direct sum of uniform matroids. It is defined over a base set in which the elements are partitioned into different categories. For each category, there is a ''capaci ...
s - 6.75 * Intersection of a graphic matroid and a partition matroid - 10.66 * General matroid with
matroid rank In the mathematical theory of matroids, the rank of a matroid is the maximum size of an independent set in the matroid. The rank of a subset ''S'' of elements of the matroid is, similarly, the maximum size of an independent subset of ''S'', and th ...
k - O(\log(k)) Moreover, they show two lower bounds: * An OPM cannot guarantee more than 1/2 the revenue of the BO auction, even in the single-item setting. * An OPM cannot guarantee more than O() the revenue of the BO auction when there are downwards-closed non-matroid constraint.
The approximation factors obtainable by an SPM are naturally better: * Uniform matroid, partition matroid - e/(e-1) ≅ 1.58 * General matroid - 2 * Intersection of two matroids - 3 The lower bound (proved by ) is approximately 1.25. Yan explains the success of the sequential-pricing approach based on the concept of
correlation gap In stochastic programming, the correlation gap is the worst-case ratio between the cost when the random variables are correlated to the cost when the random variables are independent. As an example, consider the following optimization problem. A t ...
, in the following way. The revenue of a mechanism is related to a set function f. E.g, in a k-unit auction, the function is f(S)=\min(, S, ,k) * The revenue of the BO auction is at most f(winners)\cdot Price, where "Winners" is the set of k agents with highest valuations. * The revenue of the BO SPM is at least f(Demand)\cdot Price, where "Demand" is the set of agents whose valuation is above the price. Both "Winners" and "Demand" are random-sets, determined by the agents' valuations. Moreover, by carefully setting the price, it is possible to ensure that each agent j has the same probability q_j to be in "Winners" and to be in "Demand". However, in "Winners", there is high correlation between different agents (if one agent wins, there is more probability that other agents lose), while in "Demand", the agents are independent. Therefore, the
correlation gap In stochastic programming, the correlation gap is the worst-case ratio between the cost when the random variables are correlated to the cost when the random variables are independent. As an example, consider the following optimization problem. A t ...
is an upper bound on the loss of performance when using BO SPM instead of BO auction. This gives the following approximation factors: * General matroid - e/(e-1) * k-unit auctions (a sub-case of general matroids) - 1/(1-1/\sqrt) * p-independent set systems (a generalization of the intersection of p matroids) - p+1.


Different items and one unit-demand buyer

In this setting, the seller has several different items for sale (e.g. cars of different models). There is one potential buyer, that is interested in a single item (e.g. a single car). The buyer has a different valuation for each item-type (i.e., he has a valuation-vector). Given the posted prices, the buyer buys the item that gives him the highest net utility (valuation minus price). The buyer's valuation-vector is a random-vector from a multi-dimensional probability distribution. The seller wants to compute the price-vector (a price per item) that gives him the highest expected revenue. Chawla and Hartline and Kleinberg study the case in which the buyer's valuations to the different items are independent random variables. They show that: * The revenue of the BO unit-demand pricing when there are n item-types is at most the revenue of the BO single-item auction when there are n potential buyers. * When the buyer's valuations to the different items are independent draws from the ''same'' distribution, the BO unit-demand pricing that uses the ''same'' price to all items attains at least 1/2.17 of the revenue of the BO single-item auction. * When the buyer's valuations are independent draws from different distributions, the BO unit-demand pricing that uses the same ''virtual-price'' (based on
virtual valuation In auction theory, particularly Bayesian-optimal mechanism design, a virtual valuation of an agent is a function that measures the surplus that can be extracted from that agent. A typical application is a seller who wants to sell an item to a poten ...
s) attains at least 1/3 of the revenue of the BO single-item auction. They also consider the computational task of calculating the optimal price. The main challenge is to calculate w^, the inverse of the virtual valuation function. * For ''discrete and regular'' valuation distribution, there is a polynomial-time 3-approximation. * For ''continuous and regular'' valuation distribution (available via an oracle) there is a polynomial-time (3+ε)-approximation
with high probability In mathematics, an event that occurs with high probability (often shortened to w.h.p. or WHP) is one whose probability depends on a certain number ''n'' and goes to 1 as ''n'' goes to infinity, i.e. the probability of the event occurring can be mad ...
, and a faster (6+ε)-approximation with probability 1.


Different items and many unit-demand buyers

In this setting, there are different types of items. Each buyer has different valuations for different items, and each buyer wants at most one item. Moreover, there are pre-specified constraints on the set of buyer-item pairs that can be allocated together (for example: each item can be allocated to at most one buyer; each buyer can get at most one item; etc). Chawla and Hartline and Malec and Sivan study two kinds of discriminatory pricing schemes: * In a sequential pricing mechanism (SPM), the mechanism-designer determines a price for each buyer-item pair, and an ordering on the buyer-item pairs. The mechanism loops over the buyer-item pairs in the pre-determined order. If the current buyer-item pair is feasible, then the buyer is offered the item in the pre-determined price, and he can either take it or leave it. * In an order-oblivious pricing mechanism (OPM), the mechanism-designer determines a price for each buyer-item pair. The buyers come in an arbitrary order, which may be adversarially determined after the agents' valuations are drawn. A sequential-pricing mechanism is, in general, not a
truthful mechanism In game theory, an asymmetric game where players have private information is said to be strategy-proof or strategyproof (SP) if it is a weakly-dominant strategy for every player to reveal his/her private information, i.e. given no information about ...
, since an agent may decide to decline a good offer in hopes of getting a better offer later. It is truthful only when, for every buyer, the buyer-item pairs for that buyer are ordered in decreasing order of net-utility. Then, it is always best for the buyer to accept the first offer (if its net utility is positive). A special case of that situation is the ''single-parameter setting'': for every buyer, there is only a single buyer-item pair (e.g, there is a single item for sale). To every multi-parameter setting corresponds a single-parameter setting in which each buyer-item pair is considered an independent agent. In the single-parameter setting, there is more competition (since the agents that come from the same buyer compete with each other). Therefore, the BO revenue in the single-parameter setting is an upper bound on the BO revenue in the multi-parameter setting. Therefore, if an OPM is an ''r''-approximation to the optimal mechanism for a single-parameter setting, then it is also an ''r''-approximation to the corresponding multi-parameter setting. See above for approximation factors of OPMs in various settings. See Chapter 7 "Multi-dimensional Approximation" in for more details.


Many unit-demand buyers and sellers

Recently, the SPM scheme has been extended to a
double auction A double auction is a process of buying and selling goods with multiple sellers and multiple buyers. Potential buyers submit their bids and potential sellers submit their ask prices to the market institution, and then the market institution choose ...
setting, where there are both buyers and sellers. The extended mechanism is called 2SPM. It is parametrized by an order on the buyers, an order on the sellers, and a matrix of prices - a price for each buyer-seller pair. The prices are offered to in order to buyers and sellers who may either accept or reject the offer. The approximation ratio is between 3 and 16, depending on the setting.


See also

*
Monopoly pricing A monopoly price is set by a monopoly.Roger LeRoy Miller, ''Intermediate Microeconomics Theory Issues Applications, Third Edition'', New York: McGraw-Hill, Inc, 1982.Tirole, Jean, "The Theory of Industrial Organization", Cambridge, Massachusetts: Th ...


References

{{reflist Pricing Mechanism design