Average Propensity To Consume
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

Average propensity to consume (as well as the
marginal propensity to consume In economics, the marginal propensity to consume (MPC) is a metric that quantifies induced consumption, the concept that the increase in personal consumer spending ( consumption) occurs with an increase in disposable income (income after taxes an ...
) is a concept developed by
John Maynard Keynes John Maynard Keynes, 1st Baron Keynes, ( ; 5 June 1883 – 21 April 1946), was an English economist whose ideas fundamentally changed the theory and practice of macroeconomics and the economic policies of governments. Originally trained in ...
to analyze the
consumption function In economics, the consumption function describes a relationship between consumption and disposable income. The concept is believed to have been introduced into macroeconomics by John Maynard Keynes in 1936, who used it to develop the notion of a ...
, which is a formula where total consumption expenditures (C) of a household consist of autonomous consumption (Ca) and income (Y) (or
disposable income Disposable income is total personal income minus current income taxes. In national accounts definitions, personal income minus personal current taxes equals disposable personal income. Subtracting personal outlays (which includes the major ...
(YD)) multiplied by marginal propensity to consume (c or MPC). According to Keynes, the individual´s real income determines saving and consumption decisions. Consumption function: C=+cY The average propensity to consume is referred to as the percentage of income spent on goods and services. It is the proportion of income that is consumed and it is calculated by dividing total consumption expenditure (C) by total income (Y): APC=\frac=\frac+c It can be also explained as spending on every monetary unit of income. Moreover Keynes´s theory claims that wealthier people spend less of their income on consumption than less wealthy people. This is caused by autonomous consumption as everyone needs to eat and get dressed, so they buy a certain amount of food and clothes or pay rent, they all spend some amount of money on these necessities. So the ratio is falling with higher income and wealth. This is why it seems like the poor consume more than the rich. But they only need to spent larger amount of their income on consumption because they have less money available. Average propensity to consume is not as significant as the marginal propensity to consume (MPC) which represents an additional change in consumer spending as a result of an additional change in household income per monetary unit and it is calculated as derivative of consumption function with respect to income (ratio of change in consumption to change in income). It is used for calculating multiplier in aggregate expenditures model.


Characteristics of APC


Average propensity to consume is decreasing

Since autonomous consumption in positive (Ca>0), the ratio of APC falls with increase in disposable income because with increase in income the proportion of consumption expenditures is decreasing as it creates smaller part of income. Income also rises faster than consumption. Since Keynes considered savings a luxury, he expected the rich to save more from their income than the poor.


Average propensity to consume can never be zero

The only possible way for APC to be zero is when consumption becomes zero. However, this is impossible because the consumption function includes autonomous consumption (Ca), which is always positive.


Graphical representation of average propensity to consume

Graphically is APC represented by the slope of consumption function which starts from the origin (it holds for the long run: C=cY, Ca=0). If the consumption function does not go through the origin, APC for certain income is given as the slope of the line connecting the origin and a certain point on consumption curve for a given income.


Average propensity to consume and average propensity to save (APS)

According to Keynes´s consumption and saving (S) functions and their relation to disposable income, income consists of consumption expenditure and saved income: Y=C+S=Ca+cY-Ca+sY, where ''s'' represents
marginal propensity to save The marginal propensity to save (MPS) is the fraction of an increase in income that is not spent and instead used for saving. It is the slope of the line plotting saving against income. For example, if a household earns one extra dollar, and th ...
(MPS). By dividing the equation by income we get that 1=APC+APS. Thus APC=1-APS. APC is a complement to
average propensity to save In Keynesian economics, the average propensity to save (APS), also known as the savings ratio, is the proportion of income which is saved, usually expressed for household savings as a fraction of total household disposable income (taxed income ...
. So a change in average propensity to consume also determines propensity to save. This means that the entire income of a household must be saved or spent. With increasing income households can save more (APC is decreasing).


Average propensity to consume and marginal propensity to consume (MPC)

APC>MPC holds in the short run for positive income. When income increases, APC and MPC, both fall. However, the decline in APC is smaller than the decline in MPC. And the consumption function behaves accordingly to Keynesian assumptions. In the long run, because income rises faster than consumption, with increasing income, APC converges to MPC. So MPC=APC in the long run and it is constant for Ca=0. (Mathematically from the consumption function: C=cY, after dividing it by income we get APC=(cY)/Y=c=MPC.)


APC in the short run and long run

Keynesian theory of APC, where APC>MPC, empirically works only in the short term, because it would predict “ secular stagnation” (infinity long depression) in the long run, which did not occur. This and
the Kuznets riddle ''The'' () is a grammatical Article (grammar), article in English language, English, denoting persons or things that are already or about to be mentioned, under discussion, implied or otherwise presumed familiar to listeners, readers, or speak ...
were the reasons for further development of consumption function. The Kuznets riddle asks why APC in the short run is decreasing while in the long run APC remains constant. One of the first explanations, which was wrongly almost forgotten, was provided by Duesenberry, who built on the findings of
social psychology Social psychology is the scientific study of how thoughts, feelings, and behaviors are influenced by the real or imagined presence of other people or by social norms. Social psychologists typically explain human behavior as a result of the ...
. The two best-known explanations were provided in the 1950s by Modigliani and Friedman, who built on the results of Irving Fisher's theory of intertemporal consumer choice.


Life cycle hypothesis

According to
life cycle hypothesis In economics, the life-cycle hypothesis (LCH) is a model that strives to explain the consumption patterns of individuals. Background The hypothesis Implications Saving and wealth when income and population are stable The effect of population ...
, presented by
Franco Modigliani Franco Modigliani (18 June 1918 – 25 September 2003) was an Italian-American economist and the recipient of the 1985 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics. He was a professor at University of Illinois at Urbana–Champaign, Carnegie Mellon Univ ...
, the income and consumption are dependent on stage of life. The reason for that idea is that the income fluctuates during lifetime and savings make it possible to maintain consumption at the required level even in years when income has decreased. The equation for consumption then looks as C=*W+*Y where ''W'' stands for wealth, MPCW and MPCY denote marginal propensities to consume of wealth and income, respectively. Thus average propensity to consume is equal to APC=\frac=*\frac+ APC may fluctuate for the short term but for the long term it is constant as the structure of society is stable in the long term.


Permanent income hypothesis

Permanent income hypothesis The permanent income hypothesis (PIH) is a model in the field of economics to explain the formation of consumption patterns. It suggests consumption patterns are formed from future expectations and consumption smoothing. The theory was developed ...
is
Milton Friedman Milton Friedman (; July 31, 1912 – November 16, 2006) was an American economist and statistician who received the 1976 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences for his research on consumption analysis, monetary history and theory and the ...
´s theory.  Friedman´s consumption function is given as C=MPC* where Yp denotes permanent income. Average propensity to consume is then:  APC=\frac=c*\frac According to this hypothesis, there are only changes within transitory income (Y=Yp+Yt) in the short run, the consumption does not react to those changes and people with lower income have higher APC as they spent higher proportion of their income on consumption. In the long run on the other hand, changes in income are reflected in permanent income and APC becomes constant.


See also

*
Marginal propensity to save The marginal propensity to save (MPS) is the fraction of an increase in income that is not spent and instead used for saving. It is the slope of the line plotting saving against income. For example, if a household earns one extra dollar, and th ...
*
Marginal propensity to consume In economics, the marginal propensity to consume (MPC) is a metric that quantifies induced consumption, the concept that the increase in personal consumer spending ( consumption) occurs with an increase in disposable income (income after taxes an ...
*
Average propensity to save In Keynesian economics, the average propensity to save (APS), also known as the savings ratio, is the proportion of income which is saved, usually expressed for household savings as a fraction of total household disposable income (taxed income ...


References

{{Authority control Financial ratios Gross domestic product