HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

In monotone comparative statics, the single-crossing condition or single-crossing property refers to a condition where the relationship between two or more functionsThe property need not only relate to continuous functions but can also similarly describe ordered sets or lattices. is such that they will only cross once. For example, a mean-preserving spread will result in an altered probability distribution whose
cumulative distribution function In probability theory and statistics, the cumulative distribution function (CDF) of a real-valued random variable X, or just distribution function of X, evaluated at x, is the probability that X will take a value less than or equal to x. Ev ...
will intersect with the original's only once. The single-crossing condition was posited in Samuel Karlin's 1968 monograph 'Total Positivity'. It was later used by Peter Diamond,
Joseph Stiglitz Joseph Eugene Stiglitz (; born February 9, 1943) is an American New Keynesian economist, a public policy analyst, and a full professor at Columbia University. He is a recipient of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (2001) and the Joh ...
, and
Susan Athey Susan Carleton Athey (born ) is an American economist. She is the Economics of Technology Professor in the School of Humanities and Sciences at the Stanford Graduate School of Business. Prior to joining Stanford, she has been a professor at Harva ...
, in studying the economics of uncertainty. The single-crossing condition is also used in applications where there are a few agents or types of agents that have preferences over an ordered set. Such situations appear often in information economics,
contract theory From a legal point of view, a contract is an institutional arrangement for the way in which resources flow, which defines the various relationships between the parties to a transaction or limits the rights and obligations of the parties. From an ...
, social choice and political economics, among other fields.


Example using cumulative distribution functions

Cumulative distribution functions ''F'' and ''G'' satisfy the single-crossing condition if there exists a y^* such that \forall x, x \ge y^* \implies F(x) \ge G(x) and \forall x, x \le y^* \implies F(x) \le G(x); that is, function h(x) = F(x)-G(x) crosses the x-axis at most once, in which case it does so from below. This property can be extended to two or more variables. Given x and t, for all x'>x, t'>t, F(x',t) \ge F(x,t) \implies F(x',t') \ge F(x,t') and F(x',t) > F(x,t) \implies F(x',t') > F(x,t'). This condition could be interpreted as saying that for x'>x, the function g(t)=F(x',t)-F(x,t) crosses the horizontal axis at most once, and from below. The condition is not symmetric in the variables (i.e., we cannot switch x and t in the definition; the necessary inequality in the first argument is weak, while the inequality in the second argument is strict).


Use in Social Choice

In the study of social choice, the single-crossing condition is a condition on preferences. It is especially useful because utility functions are generally increasing (i.e. the assumption that an agent will prefer or at least consider equivalent two dollars to one dollar is unobjectionable). Specifically, a set of agents with some unidimensional characteristic \alpha^i and preferences over different policies ''q'' satisfy the single crossing property when the following is true: If q > q' and \alpha^ > \alpha^i or if q < q' and \alpha^ < \alpha^i , then W(q;\alpha^i)\ge W(q';\alpha^i) \implies W(q;\alpha^)\ge W(q';\alpha^) where ''W'' is the indirect utility function. An important proposition extends the median voter theorem, which states that when voters have
single peaked preferences Single-peaked preferences are a class of preference relations. A group of agents is said to have single-peaked preferences over a set of possible outcomes if the outcomes can be ordered along a line such that: # Each agent has a "best outcome" in t ...
, a majority rule system has a Condorcet winner corresponding to the median voter's most preferred policy. With preferences that satisfy the single-crossing property, the most preferred policy of the voter with the median value of \alpha^i is the Condorcet winner. In effect, this replaces the unidimensionality of policies with the unidimensionality of voter heterogeneity. In this context, the single-crossing condition is sometimes referred to as the Gans-Smart condition.


Use in Mechanism Design

In mechanism design, the term single-crossing condition (often referred to as the Spence-Mirrlees property for
Michael Spence Andrew Michael Spence (born November 7, 1943) is a Canadian-American economist and Nobel laureate. Spence is the William R. Berkley Professor in Economics and Business at the Stern School of Business at New York University, and the Philip H. Kn ...
and James Mirrlees, sometimes as the constant-sign assumption) refers to the requirement that the isoutility curve for agents of different types cross only once. This condition guarantees that the transfer in an incentive-compatible direct mechanism can be pinned down by the transfer of the lowest type. This condition is similar to another condition called strict increasing difference (SID). Formally, suppose the agent has a utility function V(q,\theta), the SID says \forall q_2>q_1,\theta_2>\theta_1 we have V(q_2,\theta_2)-V(q_1,\theta_2)>V(q_2,\theta_1)-V(q_1,\theta_1). The Spence-Mirrlees Property is characterized by \frac(q,\theta)>0.


See also

* Brouwer fixed-point theorem


Notes


References

{{reflist Asymmetric information Fixed-point theorems