Probabilistic-serial Rule
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

A simultaneous eating algorithm (SE) is an algorithm for allocating divisible objects among agents with
ordinal preferences In economics, an ordinal utility function is a function representing the preferences of an agent on an ordinal scale. Ordinal utility theory claims that it is only meaningful to ask which option is better than the other, but it is meaningless to ask ...
. "Ordinal preferences" means that each agent can rank the items from best to worst, but cannot (or does not want to) specify a numeric value for each item. The SE allocation satisfies
SD-efficiency Ordinal Pareto efficiency refers to several adaptations of the concept of Pareto-efficiency to settings in which the agents only express ordinal utilities over items, but not over bundles. That is, agents rank the items from best to worst, but they ...
- a weak ordinal variant of Pareto-efficiency (it means that the allocation is Pareto-efficient for ''at least one'' vector of additive utility functions consistent with the agents' item rankings). SE is parametrized by the "eating speed" of each agent. If all agents are given the same eating speed, then the SE allocation satisfies SD-envy-freeness - a strong ordinal variant of
envy-freeness Envy-freeness, also known as no-envy, is a criterion for fair division. It says that, when resources are allocated among people with equal rights, each person should receive a share that is, in their eyes, at least as good as the share received by a ...
(it means that the allocation is envy-free for ''all'' vectors of additive utility functions consistent with the agents' item rankings). This particular variant of SE is called the Probabilistic Serial rule (PS). SE was developed by
Hervé Moulin Hervé Moulin (born 1950 in Paris) is a French mathematician who is the Donald J. Robertson Chair of Economics at the Adam Smith Business School at the University of Glasgow. He is known for his research contributions in mathematical economics, ...
and Anna Bogomolnaia as a solution for the
fair random assignment Fair random assignment (also called probabilistic one-sided matching) is a kind of a fair division problem. In an ''assignment problem'' (also called '' house-allocation problem'' or '' one-sided matching''), there ''m'' objects and they have to be ...
problem, where the fraction that each agent receives of each item is interpreted as a probability. If the integral of the eating speed of all agents is 1, then the sum of fractions assigned to each agent is 1, so the matrix of fractions can be decomposed into a lottery over assignments in which each agent gets exactly one item. With equal eating speeds, the lottery is
envy-free Envy-freeness, also known as no-envy, is a criterion for fair division. It says that, when resources are allocated among people with equal rights, each person should receive a share that is, in their eyes, at least as good as the share received by a ...
in expectation (
ex-ante The term ''ex-ante'' (sometimes written ''ex ante'' or ''exante'') is a phrase meaning "before the event". Ex-ante or notional demand refers to the desire for goods and services that is not backed by the ability to pay for those goods and servic ...
) for all vectors of utility functions consistent with the agents' item rankings. A variant of SE was applied also to
cake-cutting Cake-cutting may refer to: * Fair cake-cutting, a mathematical problem of fairly dividing a heterogenous resource among people with different preferences ** Efficient cake-cutting Efficient cake-cutting is a problem in economics and computer scienc ...
, where the allocation is deterministic (not random).


Description

Each item is represented as a loaf of bread (or other food). Initially, each agent goes to their favourite item and starts eating it. It is possible that several agents eat the same item at the same time. Whenever an item is fully eaten, each of the agents who ate it goes to their favorite remaining item and starts eating it in the same way, until all items are consumed. For each item, the fraction of that item eaten by each agent is recorded. In the context of random assignments,these fractions are considered as probabilities. Based on these probabilities, a lottery is done. The type of lottery depends on the problem: * If each agent is allowed to receive any number of items, then a separate lottery can be done for each item. Each item is given to one of the agents who ate a part of it, chosen at random according to the probability distribution for that item. * If each agent should receive exactly one item, then there must be a single lottery that picks an assignment by some probability distribution on the set of deterministic assignments. To do this, the ''n''-by-''n'' matrix of probabilities should be decomposed into a
convex combination In convex geometry and vector algebra, a convex combination is a linear combination of points (which can be vectors, scalars, or more generally points in an affine space) where all coefficients are non-negative and sum to 1. In other word ...
of
permutation matrices In mathematics, particularly in matrix theory, a permutation matrix is a square binary matrix that has exactly one entry of 1 in each row and each column and 0s elsewhere. Each such matrix, say , represents a permutation of elements and, when ...
. This can be done by the
Birkhoff algorithm Birkhoff's algorithm (also called Birkhoff-von-Neumann algorithm) is an algorithm for decomposing a bistochastic matrix into a convex combination of permutation matrices. It was published by Garrett Birkhoff in 1946. It has many applications. One su ...
. It is guaranteed to find a combination in which the number of permutation matrices is at most ''n''2-2''n''+2. An important parameter to SE is the ''eating speed'' of each agent. In the simplest case, when all agents have the same entitlements, it makes sense to let all agents eat in the same speed all the time. However, when agents have different entitlements, it is possible to give the more privileged agents a higher eating speed. Moreover, it is possible to let the eating speed change with time. The important thing is that the integral of the eating speed of each agent equals the total number of items that the agent should receive (in the assignment setting, each agent should get exactly 1 item, so the integral of all eating-speed functions should be 1).


Examples

There are four agents and four items (denoted w,x,y,z). The preferences of the agents are: * Alice and Bob prefer w to x to y to z. * Chana and Dana prefer x to w to z to y. The agents have equal rights so we apply SE with equal and uniform eating speed of 1 unit per minute. Initially, Alice and Bob go to w and Chana and Dana go to x. Each pair eats their item simultaneously. After 1/2 minute, Alice and Bob each have 1/2 of w, while Chana and Dana each have 1/2 of x. Then, Alice and Bob go to y (their favourite remaining item) and Chana and Dana go to z (their favourite remaining item). After 1/2 minute, Alice and Bob each have 1/2 of y and Chana and Dana each have 1/2 of z. The matrix of fractions is now:
Alice: 1/2 0 1/2 0 Bob: 1/2 0 1/2 0 Chana: 0 1/2 0 1/2 Dana: 0 1/2 0 1/2
Based on the eaten fractions, item w is given to either Alice or Bob with equal probability and the same is done with item y; item x is given to either Chana or Dana with equal probability and the same is done with item z. If it is required to give exactly 1 item per agent, then the matrix of probabilities is decomposed into the following two assignment matrices:
1 0 0 0 , , , 0 0 1 0 0 0 1 0 , , , 1 0 0 0 0 1 0 0 , , , 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 1 , , , 0 1 0 0
One of these assignments is selected at random with a probability of 1/2. Other examples can be generated at th
MatchU.ai website


Properties

The description below assumes that all agents have risk-neutral preferences, that is, their utility from a lottery equals the
expected value In probability theory, the expected value (also called expectation, expectancy, mathematical expectation, mean, average, or first moment) is a generalization of the weighted average. Informally, the expected value is the arithmetic mean of a l ...
of their utility from the outcomes.


Efficiency

SE with any vector of eating speeds satisfies an efficiency property called
SD-efficiency Ordinal Pareto efficiency refers to several adaptations of the concept of Pareto-efficiency to settings in which the agents only express ordinal utilities over items, but not over bundles. That is, agents rank the items from best to worst, but they ...
(also called ordinal efficiency). Informally it means that, considering the resulting probability matrix, there is no other matrix that all agents weakly-sd-prefer and at least one agent strictly-sd-prefers. In the context of random assignments, SD-efficiency implies ex-post efficiency: every deterministic assignment selected by the lottery is
Pareto-efficient Pareto efficiency or Pareto optimality is a situation where no action or allocation is available that makes one individual better off without making another worse off. The concept is named after Vilfredo Pareto (1848–1923), Italian civil engin ...
. A fractional assignment is SD-efficient if-and-only-if it is the outcome of SE for some vector of eating-speed functions.


Fairness

SE with equal eating speeds (called PS) satisfies a fairness property called ex-ante stochastic-dominace
envy-freeness Envy-freeness, also known as no-envy, is a criterion for fair division. It says that, when resources are allocated among people with equal rights, each person should receive a share that is, in their eyes, at least as good as the share received by a ...
(sd-envy-free). Informally it means that each agent, considering the resulting probability matrix, weakly prefers his/her own row of probabilities to the row of any other agent. Formally, for every two agents ''i'' and ''j'': * Agent ''i'' has a weakly-higher probability to get his best item in row ''i'' than in row ''j''; * Agent ''i'' has a weakly-higher probability to get one of his two best items in row ''i'' than in row ''j''; * ... * For any ''k'' ≥ 1, agent ''i'' has a weakly-higher probability to get one of his ''k'' best items in row ''i'' than in row ''j''. Note that sd-envy-freeness is guaranteed
ex-ante The term ''ex-ante'' (sometimes written ''ex ante'' or ''exante'') is a phrase meaning "before the event". Ex-ante or notional demand refers to the desire for goods and services that is not backed by the ability to pay for those goods and servic ...
: it is fair only before the lottery takes place. The algorithm is of course not
ex-post References Notes References Further reading

* * {{Latin phrases Lists of Latin phrases, E ...
fair: after the lottery takes place, the unlucky agents may envy the lucky ones. This is inevitable in allocation of indivisible objects. PS satisfies another fairness property, in addition to envy-freeness. Given any fractional allocation, for any agent ''i'' and positive integer ''k'', define ''t''(''i'',''k'') as the total fraction that agent ''i'' receives from his ''k'' topmost indifference classes. This t is a vector of size at most ''n''*''m'', where ''n'' is the number of agents and ''m'' is the number of items. An ordinally-egalitarian allocation is one that maximizes the vector t in the leximin order. PS is the unique rule that returns an ordinally-egalitarian allocation.


Strategy

SE is not a
truthful mechanism In game theory, an asymmetric game where players have private information is said to be strategy-proof or strategyproof (SP) if it is a weakly-dominant strategy for every player to reveal his/her private information, i.e. given no information about ...
: an agent who knows that his most preferred item is not wanted by any other agent, can manipulate the algorithm by eating his second-most preferred item, knowing that his best item will remain intact. The following is known about strategic manipulation of PS: * PS is truthful when agents compare bundles using the downward lexicographic relation. * An agent can compute in polynomial time a best-response w.r.t. the downward lexicographic relation. When there are two agents, each agent can compute in polynomial time a best response w.r.t. expected utility. When the number of agents can vary, computing a best response w.r.t. EU is NP-hard.. Older technical report: https://arxiv.org/abs/1401.6523. *Best responses w.r.t. expected utility can cycle. However, a pure
Nash equilibrium In game theory, the Nash equilibrium, named after the mathematician John Nash, is the most common way to define the solution of a non-cooperative game involving two or more players. In a Nash equilibrium, each player is assumed to know the equili ...
exists for any number of agents and items. When there are two agents, there are linear-time algorithms to compute a preference-profile that is in Nash equilibrium w.r.t. the original preferences. In some empirical settings, PS is less prone to manipulation. When an agent is
risk-averse In economics and finance, risk aversion is the tendency of people to prefer outcomes with low uncertainty to those outcomes with high uncertainty, even if the average outcome of the latter is equal to or higher in monetary value than the more ce ...
and has no information about the other agents' strategies, his
maximin strategy In game theory, a simultaneous game or static game is a game where each player chooses their action without knowledge of the actions chosen by other players. Simultaneous games contrast with sequential games, which are played by the players takin ...
is to be truthful. *A manipulating agent can increase his utility by a factor of at most 3/2. This was first observed empirically on random instances, and then proved formally. Note that the random priority rule, which solves the same problem as PS, is truthful.


Extensions

The SE algorithm has been extended in many ways. * Katta and Sethuraman present ''Extended PS (EPS),'' which allows weak ordinal preferences (rankings with indifferences). The algorithm is based on repeatedly solving instances of parametric network flow. * Bogomolnaia presented a simpler definition of the PS rule for weak preferences, based on the
leximin order In mathematics, leximin order is a total preorder on finite-dimensional vectors. A more accurate, but less common term is leximin preorder. The leximin order is particularly important in social choice theory and fair division. Definition A vec ...
. * Yilmaz allows both indifferences and endowments. * Athanassoglout and Sethuraman present the ''controlled consuming (CC)'' rule, which allows indifferences and fractional endowments of any quantity. * Budish, Che, Kojima and Milgrom present ''Generalized PS'', which allows multiple units per item, more items than agents, each agent can get several units, upper quotas, and bi-hierarchical constraints on the feasible allocations. * Ashlagi, Saberi and Shameli present another ''Generalized PS'', which allows lower and upper quotas, and distributional constraints (constraints on the probability distribution and not only the final allocation). * Aziz and Stursberg present ''Egalitarian Simultaneous Reservation (ESR)'', which allows not only fair item allocation but also general
social choice Social choice theory or social choice is a theoretical framework for analysis of combining individual opinions, preferences, interests, or welfares to reach a ''collective decision'' or ''social welfare'' in some sense.Amartya Sen (2008). "Soci ...
problems, with possible indifferences. * Aziz and Brandl present ''Vigilant Eating (VE)'', which allows even more general constraints.


Guaranteeing ex-post approximate fairness

As explained above, the allocation determined by PS is fair only ex-ante but not ex-post. Moreover, when each agent may get any number of items, the ex-post unfairness might be arbitrarily bad: theoretically it is possible that one agent will get all the items while other agents get none. Recently, several algorithms have been suggested, that guarantee both ex-ante fairness and ex-post approximate-fairness. Freeman, Shah and Vaish show: * The Recursive Probabilistic Serial (RecPS) algorithm, which returns a probability distribution over allocations that are all envy-free-except-one-item (EF1). The distribution is ex-ante EF, and the allocation is ex-post EF1. A naive version of this algorithm yields a distribution over a possibly exponential number of deterministic allocations, a support size polynomial in the number of agents and goods is sufficient, and thus the algorithm runs in polynomial time. The algorithm uses
separation oracle A separation oracle (also called a cutting-plane oracle) is a concept in the mathematical theory of convex optimization. It is a method to describe a convex set that is given as an input to an optimization algorithm. Separation oracles are used as ...
s. * A different algorithm, based on an ex-ante max-product allocation, which attains ex-ante
group envy-freeness Group envy-freeness (also called: coalition fairness) is a criterion for fair division. A group-envy-free division is a division of a resource among several partners such that every group of partners feel that their allocated share is at least as go ...
(GEF; it implies both EF and PO), and ex-post PROP1+EF11. This is the only allocation rule that achieves all these properties. It cannot be decomposed into EF1 allocations. *These combinations of properties are best possible: it is impossible to guarantee simultaneously ex-ante EF (even PROP) and ex-ante PO together with ex-post EF1; or ex-ante EF (even PROP) together with ex-post EF1 and fractional-PO. * The RecPS can be modified to attain similar guarantees (ex-ante EF and ex-post EF1) for bads. Aziz shows: * The PS-lottery algorithm, in which the allocation is ex-ante sd-EF, and the lottery is done only among deterministic allocations that are sd-EF1, i.e., the EF and EF1 guarantees hold for ''any'' cardinal utilities consistent with the ordinal ranking. Moreover, the outcome is sd-PO both ex-ante and ex-post. The algorithm uses as subroutines both the PS algorithm and the
Birkhoff algorithm Birkhoff's algorithm (also called Birkhoff-von-Neumann algorithm) is an algorithm for decomposing a bistochastic matrix into a convex combination of permutation matrices. It was published by Garrett Birkhoff in 1946. It has many applications. One su ...
. The ex-ante allocation is equivalent to the one returned by PS; this shows that the outcome of PS can be decomposed into EF1 allocations. *With binary utilities, the PS-lottery algorithm is group-
strategyproof In game theory, an asymmetric game where players have private information is said to be strategy-proof or strategyproof (SP) if it is a weakly-dominant strategy for every player to reveal his/her private information, i.e. given no information about ...
, ex-ante PO, ex-ante EF and ex-post EF1. *These combinations of properties are best possible: it is impossible to guarantee simultaneously ex-ante sd-EF, ex-post EF1 and ex-post PO; or ex-ante PO and ex-ante sd-EF. * Checking whether a ''given'' random allocation can be implemented by a lottery over EF1 and PO allocations is NP-hard. Babaioff, Ezra and Feige show: * A polynomial-time algorithm for computing allocations that are ex-ante proportional, and ex-post both PROP1 and 1/2-fraction
maximin-share Maximin share (MMS) is a criterion of fair item allocation. Given a set of items with different values, the ''1-out-of-n maximin-share'' is the maximum value that can be gained by partitioning the items into ''n'' parts and taking the part with th ...
(and also 1/2-fraction ''truncated-proportional share''). * These properties are nearly optimal - it is impossible to guarantee more than PROP ex-ante, and more than ''n''/(2''n''-1) truncated-proportional share ex-post. Hoefer, Schmalhofer and Varricchio extend the notion of "Best-of-Both-Worlds" lottery to agents with different
entitlements An entitlement is a provision (accounting), provision made in accordance with a law, legal framework of a society. Typically, entitlements are based on concepts of principle ("rights") which are themselves based in concepts of social equality or en ...
.


See also

The page on
fair random assignment Fair random assignment (also called probabilistic one-sided matching) is a kind of a fair division problem. In an ''assignment problem'' (also called '' house-allocation problem'' or '' one-sided matching''), there ''m'' objects and they have to be ...
compares PS to other procedures for solving the same problem, such as the random priority rule.


References

{{reflist Fair division protocols