HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

Pareto efficiency or Pareto optimality is a situation where no action or allocation is available that makes one individual better off without making another worse off. The concept is named after Vilfredo Pareto (1848–1923), Italian
civil engineer A civil engineer is a person who practices civil engineering – the application of planning, designing, constructing, maintaining, and operating infrastructure while protecting the public and environmental health, as well as improving existing ...
and economist, who used the concept in his studies of
economic efficiency In microeconomics, economic efficiency, depending on the context, is usually one of the following two related concepts: * Allocative or Pareto efficiency: any changes made to assist one person would harm another. * Productive efficiency: no addit ...
and income distribution. The following three concepts are closely related: * Given an initial situation, a Pareto improvement is a new situation where some agents will gain, and no agents will lose. * A situation is called Pareto-dominated if there exists a possible Pareto improvement. * A situation is called Pareto-optimal or Pareto-efficient if no change could lead to improved satisfaction for some agent without some other agent losing or, equivalently, if there is no scope for further Pareto improvement. The Pareto front (also called Pareto frontier or Pareto set) is the set of all Pareto-efficient situations. Pareto originally used the word "optimal" for the concept, but as it describes a situation where a limited number of people will be made better off under finite resources, and it does not take equality or social well-being into account, it is in effect a definition of and better captured by "efficiency". In addition to the context of efficiency in ''allocation'', the concept of Pareto efficiency also arises in the context of ''efficiency in production'' vs. '' x-inefficiency'': a set of outputs of goods is Pareto-efficient if there is no feasible re-allocation of productive inputs such that output of one product increases while the outputs of all other goods either increase or remain the same. Pareto efficiency is measured along the production possibility frontier (PPF), which is a graphical representation of all the possible options of output for two products that can be produced using all factors of production. Besides economics, the notion of Pareto efficiency has been applied to the selection of alternatives in engineering and biology. Each option is first assessed, under multiple criteria, and then a subset of options is ostensibly identified with the property that no other option can categorically outperform the specified option. It is a statement of impossibility of improving one variable without harming other variables in the subject of multi-objective optimization (also termed Pareto optimization).


Overview

Formally, a state is Pareto-optimal if there is no alternative state where improvements can be made to at least one participant's well-being without reducing any other participant's well-being. If there is a state change that satisfies this condition, the new state is called a "Pareto improvement". When no Pareto improvements are possible, the state is a "Pareto optimum". In other words, Pareto efficiency is when it is impossible to make one party better off without making another party worse off. This state indicates that resources can no longer be allocated in a way that makes one party better off without harming other parties. In a state of Pareto Efficiency, resources are allocated in the most efficient way possible. Pareto efficiency is mathematically represented when there is no other strategy profile ''s’'' such that ''ui (s’) ≥ ui (s)'' for every player ''i'' and ''uj (s’) >  uj (s)'' for some player ''j''. In this equation ''s'' represents the strategy profile, ''u'' represents the utility or benefit, and ''j'' represents the player. Efficiency is an important criterion for judging behavior in a game. In a notable and often analyzed game known as
Prisoner’s Dilemma The Prisoner's Dilemma is an example of a game analyzed in game theory. It is also a thought experiment that challenges two completely rational agents to a dilemma: cooperate with their partner for mutual reward, or betray their partner ("def ...
, depicted below as a
normal form game In game theory, normal form is a description of a ''game''. Unlike extensive form, normal-form representations are not graphical ''per se'', but rather represent the game by way of a matrix. While this approach can be of greater use in identifying ...
, this concept of efficiency can be observed, in that the strategy profile (Cooperate, Cooperate) is more efficient than (Defect, Defect). Using the definition listed above, ''u(Ci)'' ≥ ''u(Di)'' for ''i ∈'' , thus yielding this strategy as a Pareto efficient strategy. In other words, both players receive an increase in payoff by selecting Cooperate over Defect. A special case of a state is an allocation of resources. The formal presentation of the concept in an economy is the following: Consider an economy with n agents and k goods. Then an allocation \ , where x_i \in \mathbb^k for all ''i'', is ''Pareto-optimal'' if there is no other feasible allocation \ where, for utility function u_i for each agent i , u_i(x_i') \geq u_i(x_i) for all i \in \ with u_i(x_i') > u_i(x_i) for some i.. Here, in this simple economy, "feasibility" refers to an allocation where the total amount of each good that is allocated sums to no more than the total amount of the good in the economy. In a more complex economy with production, an allocation would consist both of consumption vectors and production vectors, and feasibility would require that the total amount of each consumed good is no greater than the initial endowment plus the amount produced. Under the assumptions of the
first welfare theorem There are two fundamental theorems of welfare economics. The first states that in economic equilibrium, a set of complete markets, with complete information, and in perfect competition, will be Pareto optimal (in the sense that no further exchang ...
, a competitive market leads to a Pareto-efficient outcome. This result was first demonstrated mathematically by economists Kenneth Arrow and
Gérard Debreu Gérard Debreu (; 4 July 1921 – 31 December 2004) was a French-born economist and mathematician. Best known as a professor of economics at the University of California, Berkeley, where he began work in 1962, he won the 1983 Nobel Memorial Prize ...
. However, the result only holds under the assumptions of the theorem: markets exist for all possible goods, there are no externalities, markets are perfectly competitive, and market participants have
perfect information In economics, perfect information (sometimes referred to as "no hidden information") is a feature of perfect competition. With perfect information in a market, all consumers and producers have complete and instantaneous knowledge of all market pr ...
. In the absence of perfect information or complete markets, outcomes will generally be Pareto-inefficient, per the Greenwald–Stiglitz theorem. The second welfare theorem is essentially the reverse of the first welfare theorem. It states that under similar, ideal assumptions, any Pareto optimum can be obtained by some competitive equilibrium, or free market system, although it may also require a lump-sum transfer of wealth.


Variants


Weak Pareto efficiency

Weak Pareto efficiency is a situation that cannot be strictly improved for ''every'' individual. Formally, a strong Pareto improvement is defined as a situation in which all agents are strictly better-off (in contrast to just "Pareto improvement", which requires that one agent is strictly better-off and the other agents are at least as good). A situation is weak Pareto-efficient if it has no strong Pareto improvements. Any strong Pareto improvement is also a weak Pareto improvement. The opposite is not true; for example, consider a resource allocation problem with two resources, which Alice values at , and George values at . Consider the allocation giving all resources to Alice, where the utility profile is (10, 0): * It is a weak PO, since no other allocation is strictly better to both agents (there are no strong Pareto improvements). * But it is not a strong PO, since the allocation in which George gets the second resource is strictly better for George and weakly better for Alice (it is a weak Pareto improvement) its utility profile is (10, 5). A market doesn't require local nonsatiation to get to a weak Pareto optimum.


Constrained Pareto efficiency

Constrained Pareto efficiency is a weakening of Pareto optimality, accounting for the fact that a potential planner (e.g., the government) may not be able to improve upon a decentralized market outcome, even if that outcome is inefficient. This will occur if it is limited by the same informational or institutional constraints as are individual agents. An example is of a setting where individuals have private information (for example, a labor market where the worker's own productivity is known to the worker but not to a potential employer, or a used-car market where the quality of a car is known to the seller but not to the buyer) which results in moral hazard or an adverse selection and a sub-optimal outcome. In such a case, a planner who wishes to improve the situation is unlikely to have access to any information that the participants in the markets do not have. Hence, the planner cannot implement allocation rules which are based on the idiosyncratic characteristics of individuals; for example, "if a person is of type ''A'', they pay price ''p''1, but if of type ''B'', they pay price ''p''2" (see
Lindahl prices Lindahl is a Swedish surname which may refer to People * Anna Lindahl (1904–1952), Swedish film actress *Axel Lindahl (1841–1906), Swedish photographer * Axel Lindahl (athlete) (born 1995), Swedish footballer * Axel Lindahl (footbal ...
). Essentially, only anonymous rules are allowed (of the sort "Everyone pays price ''p''") or rules based on observable behavior; "if any person chooses ''x'' at price ''px'', then they get a subsidy of ten dollars, and nothing otherwise". If there exists no allowed rule that can successfully improve upon the market outcome, then that outcome is said to be "constrained Pareto-optimal".


Fractional Pareto efficiency

Fractional Pareto efficiency is a strengthening of Pareto efficiency in the context of fair item allocation. An allocation of indivisible items is fractionally Pareto-efficient (fPE or fPO) if it is not Pareto-dominated even by an allocation in which some items are split between agents. This is in contrast to standard Pareto efficiency, which only considers domination by feasible (discrete) allocations.Barman, S., Krishnamurthy, S. K., & Vaish, R.
"Finding Fair and Efficient Allocations"
''EC '18: Proceedings of the 2018 ACM Conference on Economics and Computation'', June 2018.
As an example, consider an item allocation problem with two items, which Alice values at and George values at . Consider the allocation giving the first item to Alice and the second to George, where the utility profile is (3, 1): * It is Pareto-efficient, since any other discrete allocation (without splitting items) makes someone worse-off. * However, it is not fractionally Pareto-efficient, since it is Pareto-dominated by the allocation giving to Alice 1/2 of the first item and the whole second item, and the other 1/2 of the first item to George its utility profile is (3.5, 2).


Ex-ante Pareto efficiency

When the decision process is random, such as in
fair random assignment Fair random assignment (also called probabilistic one-sided matching) is a kind of a fair division problem. In an ''assignment problem'' (also called '' house-allocation problem'' or '' one-sided matching''), there ''m'' objects and they have to be ...
or
random social choice Fractional social choice is a branch of social choice theory in which the collective decision is not a single alternative, but rather a weighted sum of two or more alternatives. For example, if society has to choose between three candidates: A B or ...
or
fractional approval voting Fractional approval voting is an electoral system using approval ballots (each voter selects one or more candidate alternatives), in which the outcome is ''fractional'': for each alternative ''j'' there is a fraction ''pj'' between 0 and 1, such tha ...
, there is a difference between ex-post and ex-ante Pareto efficiency: * Ex-post Pareto efficiency means that any outcome of the random process is Pareto-efficient. * Ex-ante Pareto efficiency means that the ''lottery'' determined by the process is Pareto-efficient with respect to the ''expected'' utilities. That is: no other lottery gives a higher expected utility to one agent and at least as high expected utility to all agents. If some lottery ''L'' is ex-ante PE, then it is also ex-post PE. ''Proof'': suppose that one of the ex-post outcomes ''x'' of ''L'' is Pareto-dominated by some other outcome ''y''. Then, by moving some probability mass from ''x'' to ''y'', one attains another lottery ''L'' that ex-ante Pareto-dominates ''L''. The opposite is not true: ex-ante PE is stronger that ex-post PE. For example, suppose there are two objects a car and a house. Alice values the car at 2 and the house at 3; George values the car at 2 and the house at 9. Consider the following two lotteries: # With probability 1/2, give car to Alice and house to George; otherwise, give car to George and house to Alice. The expected utility is for Alice and for George. Both allocations are ex-post PE, since the one who got the car cannot be made better-off without harming the one who got the house. # With probability 1, give car to Alice, then with probability 1/3 give the house to Alice, otherwise give it to George. The expected utility is for Alice and for George. Again, both allocations are ex-post PE. While both lotteries are ex-post PE, the lottery 1 is not ex-ante PE, since it is Pareto-dominated by lottery 2. Another example involves
dichotomous preferences In economics, dichotomous preferences (DP) are preference relations that divide the set of alternatives to two subsets: "Good" versus "Bad". From ordinal utility perspective, DP means that for every two alternatives X,Y: : X \preceq Y \iff X \in ...
. There are 5 possible outcomes and 6 voters. The voters' approval sets are . All five outcomes are PE, so every lottery is ex-post PE. But the lottery selecting ''c'', ''d'', ''e'' with probability 1/3 each is not ex-ante PE, since it gives an expected utility of 1/3 to each voter, while the lottery selecting ''a'', ''b'' with probability 1/2 each gives an expected utility of 1/2 to each voter.


Bayesian Pareto efficiency

Bayesian efficiency is an adaptation of Pareto efficiency to settings in which players have incomplete information regarding the types of other players.


Ordinal Pareto efficiency

Ordinal Pareto efficiency is an adaptation of Pareto efficiency to settings in which players report only rankings on individual items, and we do not know for sure how they rank entire bundles.


Pareto efficiency and equity

Although an outcome may be considered a Pareto improvement, this does not imply that the outcome is satisfying or equitable. It is possible that inequality persists even after a Pareto improvement. Despite the fact that it is frequently used in conjunction with the idea of Pareto optimality, the term "efficiency" refers to the process of increasing societal productivity. It is possible for a society to have Pareto efficiency while also have high levels of inequality. Consider the following scenario: there is a pie and three persons; the most equitable way would be to divide the pie into three equal portions. However, if the pie is divided in half and shared between two people, it is considered Pareto efficient meaning that the third person does not lose out (despite the fact that he does not receive a piece of the pie). When making judgments, it is critical to consider a variety of aspects, including social efficiency, overall welfare, and issues such as diminishing marginal value.


Pareto efficiency and market failure

In order to fully understand market failure, one must first comprehend market success, which is defined as the ability of a set of idealized competitive markets to achieve an equilibrium allocation of resources that is Pareto-optimal in terms of resource allocation. According to the definition of market failure, it is a circumstance in which the conclusion of the first fundamental theorem of welfare is erroneous; that is, when the allocations made through markets are not efficient. In a free market, market failure is defined as an inefficient allocation of resources. Due to the fact that it is feasible to improve, market failure implies Pareto inefficiency. For example, excessive consumption of depreciating items (drugs/tobacco) results in external costs to non-smokers, as well as premature death for smokers who do not quit. An increase in the price of cigarettes could motivate people to quit smoking while also raising funds for the treatment of smoking-related ailments.


Approximate Pareto efficiency

Given some ''ε'' > 0, an outcome is called ''ε''-Pareto-efficient if no other outcome gives all agents at least the same utility, and one agent a utility at least (1 + ''ε'') higher. This captures the notion that improvements smaller than (1 + ''ε'') are negligible and should not be considered a breach of efficiency.


Pareto-efficiency and welfare-maximization

Suppose each agent ''i'' is assigned a positive weight ''ai''. For every allocation ''x'', define the ''welfare'' of ''x'' as the weighted sum of utilities of all agents in ''x'': : W_a(x) := \sum_^n a_i u_i(x). Let ''xa'' be an allocation that maximizes the welfare over all allocations: : x_a \in \arg\max_x W_a(x). It is easy to show that the allocation ''xa'' is Pareto-efficient: since all weights are positive, any Pareto improvement would increase the sum, contradicting the definition of ''xa''. Japanese neo- Walrasian economist
Takashi Negishi is a Japanese neo- Walrasian economist. Career Negishi graduated Faculty of Economics, University of Tokyo in 1956 and received a PhD in Economics from University of Tokyo in 1963. Contributions Negishi's research has provided a wide range of e ...
proved that, under certain assumptions, the opposite is also true: for ''every'' Pareto-efficient allocation ''x'', there exists a positive vector ''a'' such that ''x'' maximizes ''Wa''. A shorter proof is provided by Hal Varian.


Use in engineering

The notion of Pareto efficiency has been used in engineering. Given a set of choices and a way of valuing them, the Pareto front (or Pareto set or Pareto frontier) is the set of choices that are Pareto-efficient. By restricting attention to the set of choices that are Pareto-efficient, a designer can make trade-offs within this set, rather than considering the full range of every parameter.


Use in public policy

Modern microeconomic theory has drawn heavily upon the concept of Pareto efficiency for inspiration. Pareto and his successors have tended to describe this technical definition of optimal resource allocation in the context of it being an equilibrium that can theoretically be achieved within an abstract model of market competition. It has therefore very often been treated as a corroboration of
Adam Smith Adam Smith (baptized 1723 – 17 July 1790) was a Scottish economist and philosopher who was a pioneer in the thinking of political economy and key figure during the Scottish Enlightenment. Seen by some as "The Father of Economics"——— ...
's " invisible hand" notion. More specifically, it motivated the debate over " market socialism" in the 1930s. However, because the Pareto-efficient outcome is difficult to assess in the real world when issues including asymmetric information, signalling, adverse selection, and moral hazard are introduced, most people do not take the theorems of welfare economics as accurate descriptions of the real world. Therefore, the significance of the two welfare theorems of economics is in their ability to generate a framework that has dominated neoclassical thinking about public policy. That framework is that the welfare economics theorems allow the political economy to be studied in the following two situations: "market failure" and "the problem of redistribution".Lockwood B. (2008) ''Pareto Efficiency''. In: Palgrave Macmillan (eds.) ''The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics''. Palgrave Macmillan, London. Analysis of "market failure" can be understood by the literature surrounding externalities. When comparing the "real" economy to the complete contingent markets economy (which is considered efficient), the inefficiencies become clear. These inefficiencies, or externalities, are then able to be addressed by mechanisms, including property rights and corrective taxes. Analysis of "the problem with redistribution" deals with the observed political question of how income or commodity taxes should be utilized. The theorem tells us that no taxation is Pareto-efficient and that taxation with redistribution is Pareto-inefficient. Because of this, most of the literature is focused on finding solutions where given there is a tax structure, how can the tax structure prescribe a situation where no person could be made better off by a change in available taxes.


Use in biology

Pareto optimisation has also been studied in biological processes. In bacteria,
genes In biology, the word gene (from , ; "...Wilhelm Johannsen coined the word gene to describe the Mendelian units of heredity..." meaning ''generation'' or ''birth'' or ''gender'') can have several different meanings. The Mendelian gene is a ba ...
were shown to be either inexpensive to make (resource-efficient) or easier to read ( translation-efficient). Natural selection acts to push highly expressed genes towards the Pareto frontier for resource use and translational efficiency. Genes near the Pareto frontier were also shown to evolve more slowly (indicating that they are providing a selective advantage).


Common misconceptions

It would be incorrect to treat Pareto efficiency as equivalent to societal optimization, as the latter is a normative concept, which is a matter of interpretation that typically would account for the consequence of degrees of inequality of distribution. An example would be the interpretation of one school district with low property tax revenue versus another with much higher revenue as a sign that more equal distribution occurs with the help of government redistribution.


Criticism

Some commentators contest that Pareto efficiency could potentially serve as an ideological tool. With it implying that capitalism is self-regulated thereof, it is likely that the embedded structural problems such as unemployment would be treated as deviating from the equilibrium or norm, and thus neglected or discounted. Pareto efficiency does not require a totally equitable distribution of wealth, which is another aspect that draws in criticism. An economy in which a wealthy few hold the vast majority of resources can be Pareto-efficient. A simple example is the distribution of a pie among three people. The most equitable distribution would assign one third to each person. However, the assignment of, say, a half section to each of two individuals and none to the third is also Pareto-optimal despite not being equitable, because none of the recipients could be made better off without decreasing someone else's share; and there are many other such distribution examples. An example of a Pareto-inefficient distribution of the pie would be allocation of a quarter of the pie to each of the three, with the remainder discarded. The liberal paradox elaborated by Amartya Sen shows that when people have preferences about what other people do, the goal of Pareto efficiency can come into conflict with the goal of individual liberty.Sen, A., ''Rationality and Freedom'' ( Cambridge, MA / London: Belknep Press, 2004)
pp. 92–94
Lastly, it is proposed that Pareto efficiency to some extent inhibited discussion of other possible criteria of efficiency. As Wharton School professor Ben Lockwood argues, one possible reason is that any other efficiency criteria established in the neoclassical domain will reduce to Pareto efficiency at the end.


See also

*
Admissible decision rule In statistical decision theory, an admissible decision rule is a rule for making a decision such that there is no other rule that is always "better" than it (or at least sometimes better and never worse), in the precise sense of "better" defined ...
, analog in decision theory * Arrow's impossibility theorem *
Bayesian efficiency Bayesian efficiency is an analog of Pareto efficiency for situations in which there is incomplete information.Palfrey, Thomas R.; Srivastava, Sanjay; Postlewaite, A. (1993) Bayesian Implementation.' Pg. 13-14. Under Pareto efficiency, an allocati ...
*
Fundamental theorems of welfare economics There are two fundamental theorems of welfare economics. The first states that in economic equilibrium, a set of complete markets, with complete information, and in perfect competition, will be Pareto optimal (in the sense that no further exchange ...
* Deadweight loss *
Economic efficiency In microeconomics, economic efficiency, depending on the context, is usually one of the following two related concepts: * Allocative or Pareto efficiency: any changes made to assist one person would harm another. * Productive efficiency: no addit ...
*
Highest and best use Highest and Best Use, or highest or best use (HBU), is a concept that originated with early economists such as Irving Fisher (1867-1947), who conceptualized the idea of maximum productivity. One of the earliest citations of the term is found in th ...
* Kaldor–Hicks efficiency * Market failure, when a market result is not Pareto-optimal *
Maximal element In mathematics, especially in order theory, a maximal element of a subset ''S'' of some preordered set is an element of ''S'' that is not smaller than any other element in ''S''. A minimal element of a subset ''S'' of some preordered set is defin ...
, concept in order theory *
Maxima of a point set In computational geometry, a point in a finite set of points is said to be ''maximal'' or ''non-dominated'' if there is no other point in whose coordinates are all greater than or equal to the corresponding coordinates of . The maxima of a poi ...
* Multi-objective optimization * Pareto-efficient envy-free division * '' Social Choice and Individual Values'' for the "(weak) Pareto principle" *
TOTREP Trade-off talking rational economic person (TOTREP) is one term, among others, used to denote, in the field of choice analysis, the rational, human agent of economic decisions. Origin of the term The term was first used notably in David M. Kreps' ' ...
* Welfare economics


References


Further reading

* * * * *
Book preview.
* * {{DEFAULTSORT:Pareto Efficiency Game theory Law and economics Welfare economics Mathematical optimization Electoral system criteria Vilfredo Pareto