HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

In mathematics, majorization is a preorder on vectors of real numbers. Let ^_,\ i=1,\,\ldots,\,n denote the i-th largest element of the vector \mathbf\in\mathbb^n. Given \mathbf,\ \mathbf \in \mathbb^n, we say that \mathbf weakly majorizes (or dominates) \mathbf from below (or equivalently, we say that \mathbf is weakly majorized (or dominated) by \mathbf from below) denoted as \mathbf \succ_w \mathbf if \sum_^k x_^ \geq \sum_^k y_^ for all k=1,\,\dots,\,d. If in addition \sum_^d x_i^ = \sum_^d y_i^, we say that \mathbf majorizes (or dominates) \mathbf , written as \mathbf \succ \mathbf , or equivalently, we say that \mathbf is majorized (or dominated) by \mathbf. The order of the entries of the vectors \mathbf or \mathbf does not affect the majorization, e.g., the statement (1,2)\prec (0,3) is simply equivalent to (2,1)\prec (3,0). As a consequence, majorization is not a
partial order In mathematics, especially order theory, a partially ordered set (also poset) formalizes and generalizes the intuitive concept of an ordering, sequencing, or arrangement of the elements of a set. A poset consists of a set together with a bina ...
, since \mathbf \succ \mathbf and \mathbf \succ \mathbf do not imply \mathbf = \mathbf , it only implies that the components of each vector are equal, but not necessarily in the same order. The majorization partial order on finite dimensional vectors, described here, can be generalized to the Lorenz ordering, a partial order on distribution functions. For example, a
wealth distribution The distribution of wealth is a comparison of the wealth of various members or groups in a society. It shows one aspect of economic inequality or economic heterogeneity. The distribution of wealth differs from the income distribution in tha ...
is Lorenz-greater than another if its
Lorenz curve In economics, the Lorenz curve is a graphical representation of the distribution of income or of wealth. It was developed by Max O. Lorenz in 1905 for representing inequality of the wealth distribution. The curve is a graph showing the proportio ...
lies below the other. As such, a Lorenz-greater wealth distribution has a higher Gini coefficient, and has more
income disparity There are wide varieties of economic inequality, most notably income inequality measured using the distribution of income (the amount of money people are paid) and wealth inequality measured using the distribution of wealth (the amount of we ...
. Various other generalizations of majorization are discussed in chapters 14 and 15 of.


Examples

(Strong) majorization: (1,2,3)\prec (0,3,3)\prec (0,0,6). For vectors with n components : \left(\frac, \ldots, \frac\right)\prec \left(\frac, \ldots, \frac,0\right) \prec \cdots \prec \left(\frac,\frac, 0, \ldots, 0\right) \prec \left(1, 0, \ldots, 0\right). (Weak) majorization: (1,2,3)\prec_w (1,3,3)\prec_w (1,3,4). For vectors with n components: : \left(\frac, \ldots, \frac\right)\prec_w \left(\frac, \ldots, \frac,1\right).


Geometry of majorization

For \mathbf,\ \mathbf \in \mathbb^n, we have \mathbf \prec \mathbf if and only if \mathbf is in the convex hull of all vectors obtained by permuting the coordinates of \mathbf. Figure 1 displays the convex hull in 2D for the vector \mathbf=(3,\,1). Notice that the center of the convex hull, which is an interval in this case, is the vector \mathbf=(2,\,2). This is the "smallest" vector satisfying \mathbf \prec \mathbf for this given vector \mathbf. Figure 2 shows the convex hull in 3D. The center of the convex hull, which is a 2D polygon in this case, is the "smallest" vector \mathbf satisfying \mathbf \prec \mathbf for this given vector \mathbf.


Schur convexity

A function f:\mathbb^n \to \mathbb is said to be Schur convex when \mathbf \succ \mathbf implies f(\mathbf) \geq f(\mathbf). Hence, Schur-convex functions translate the ordering of vectors to a standard ordering in \mathbb. Similarly, f(\mathbf) is Schur concave when \mathbf \succ \mathbf implies f(\mathbf) \leq f(\mathbf). An example of a Schur-convex function is the max function, \max(\mathbf)=x_^. Schur convex functions are necessarily symmetric that the entries of it argument can be switched without modifying the value of the function. Therefore, linear functions, which are convex, are not Schur-convex unless they are symmetric. If a function is symmetric and convex, then it is Schur-convex.


Equivalent conditions

Each of the following statements is true if and only if \mathbf\succ \mathbf: * \mathbf = \mathbf\mathbf for some
doubly stochastic matrix In mathematics, especially in probability and combinatorics, a doubly stochastic matrix (also called bistochastic matrix) is a square matrix X=(x_) of nonnegative real numbers, each of whose rows and columns sums to 1, i.e., :\sum_i x_=\sum_j x_=1 ...
\mathbf.Barry C. Arnold. "Majorization and the Lorenz Order: A Brief Introduction". Springer-Verlag Lecture Notes in Statistics, vol. 43, 1987. This is equivalent to saying \mathbf can be represented as a
convex combination In convex geometry and vector algebra, a convex combination is a linear combination of points (which can be vectors, scalars, or more generally points in an affine space) where all coefficients are non-negative and sum to 1. In other w ...
of the permutations of \mathbf; one can verify that there exists such a convex representation using at most n permutations of \mathbf. * From \mathbf we can produce \mathbf by a finite sequence of "Robin Hood operations" where we replace two elements x_i and x_j < x_i with x_i-\varepsilon and x_j+\varepsilon, respectively, for some \varepsilon \in (0, x_i-x_j). * For every convex function h:\mathbb\to \mathbb, \sum_^d h(x_i) \geq \sum_^d h(y_i). **In fact, a special case suffices: \sum_i=\sum_i and, for every , \sum_^d \max(0,x_i-t) \geq\sum_^d \max(0,y_i-t).July 3, 2005 post by fleeting_guest o
"The Karamata Inequality" thread
AoPS community forums.
Archived
11 November 2020.
* \forall t \in \mathbb \quad \sum_^d , x_j-t, \geq \sum_^d , y_j-t, .


In linear algebra

* Suppose that for two real vectors \mathbf,\ \mathbf \in \mathbb^d, \mathbf majorizes \mathbf. Then it can be shown that there exists a set of probabilities (p_1,p_2,\ldots,p_d),\ \sum_^d p_i=1 and a set of permutations (P_1,P_2,\ldots,P_d) such that \mathbf=\sum_^d p_iP_i\mathbf. Alternatively it can be shown that there exists a
doubly stochastic matrix In mathematics, especially in probability and combinatorics, a doubly stochastic matrix (also called bistochastic matrix) is a square matrix X=(x_) of nonnegative real numbers, each of whose rows and columns sums to 1, i.e., :\sum_i x_=\sum_j x_=1 ...
\mathbf such that \mathbf\mathbf=\mathbf *We say that a
Hermitian operator In mathematics, a self-adjoint operator on an infinite-dimensional complex vector space ''V'' with inner product \langle\cdot,\cdot\rangle (equivalently, a Hermitian operator in the finite-dimensional case) is a linear map ''A'' (from ''V'' to it ...
, \mathbf, majorizes another, \mathbf, if the set of eigenvalues of \mathbf majorizes that of \mathbf.


In computability theory

Given f, \ g : \mathbb \to\mathbb, then f is said to ''majorize'' g if, for all x, f(x)\geq g(x). If there is some n so that f(x)\geq g(x) for all x > n, then f is said to ''dominate'' (or ''eventually dominate'') g. Alternatively, the preceding terms are often defined requiring the strict inequality f(x) > g(x) instead of f(x)\geq g(x) in the foregoing definitions.


See also

*
Muirhead's inequality In mathematics, Muirhead's inequality, named after Robert Franklin Muirhead, also known as the "bunching" method, generalizes the inequality of arithmetic and geometric means. Preliminary definitions ''a''-mean For any real vector :a=(a_1,\dots ...
* Karamata's Inequality * Schur-convex function * Schur–Horn theorem relating diagonal entries of a matrix to its eigenvalues. * For positive
integer number An integer is the number zero (), a positive natural number (, , , etc.) or a negative integer with a minus sign (−1, −2, −3, etc.). The negative numbers are the additive inverses of the corresponding positive numbers. In the language of ...
s, weak majorization is called
Dominance order In discrete mathematics, dominance order (synonyms: dominance ordering, majorization order, natural ordering) is a partial order on the set of partitions of a positive integer ''n'' that plays an important role in algebraic combinatorics and repr ...
. *
Leximin order In mathematics, leximin order is a total preorder on finite-dimensional vectors. A more accurate, but less common term is leximin preorder. The leximin order is particularly important in social choice theory and fair division. Definition A vec ...


Notes


References

* J. Karamata. "Sur une inegalite relative aux fonctions convexes." ''Publ. Math. Univ. Belgrade'' 1, 145–158, 1932. * G. H. Hardy, J. E. Littlewood and G. Pólya, ''Inequalities'', 2nd edition, 1952, Cambridge University Press, London. * ''Inequalities: Theory of Majorization and Its Applications'' Albert W. Marshall,
Ingram Olkin Ingram Olkin (July 23, 1924 – April 28, 2016) was a professor emeritus and chair of statistics and education at Stanford University and the Stanford Graduate School of Education. He is known for developing statistical analysis for evalua ...
, Barry Arnold, Second edition. Springer Series in Statistics. Springer, New York, 2011.
A tribute to Marshall and Olkin's book "Inequalities: Theory of Majorization and its Applications"
* ''Matrix Analysis'' (1996) Rajendra Bhatia, Springer, * ''Topics in Matrix Analysis'' (1994) Roger A. Horn and Charles R. Johnson, Cambridge University Press, * ''Majorization and Matrix Monotone Functions in Wireless Communications'' (2007) Eduard Jorswieck and Holger Boche, Now Publishers, * ''The Cauchy Schwarz Master Class'' (2004) J. Michael Steele, Cambridge University Press, {{ISBN, 978-0-521-54677-5


External links






Software

* OCTAVE/
MATLAB MATLAB (an abbreviation of "MATrix LABoratory") is a proprietary multi-paradigm programming language and numeric computing environment developed by MathWorks. MATLAB allows matrix manipulations, plotting of functions and data, implementa ...
br>code to check majorization
Order theory Linear algebra