HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

In macroeconomics, multiplier uncertainty is lack of perfect knowledge of the multiplier effect of a particular policy action, such as a monetary or fiscal policy change, upon the intended target of the policy. For example, a
fiscal policy In economics and political science, fiscal policy is the use of government revenue collection (taxes or tax cuts) and expenditure to influence a country's economy. The use of government revenue expenditures to influence macroeconomic variab ...
maker may have a prediction as to the value of the fiscal multiplier—the ratio of the effect of a government spending change on
GDP Gross domestic product (GDP) is a monetary measure of the market value of all the final goods and services produced and sold (not resold) in a specific time period by countries. Due to its complex and subjective nature this measure is ofte ...
to the size of the government spending change—but is not likely to know the exact value of this ratio. Similar uncertainty may surround the magnitude of effect of a change in the monetary base or its growth rate upon some target variable, which could be the
money supply In macroeconomics, the money supply (or money stock) refers to the total volume of currency held by the public at a particular point in time. There are several ways to define "money", but standard measures usually include currency in circul ...
, the exchange rate, the
inflation rate In economics, inflation is an increase in the general price level of goods and services in an economy. When the general price level rises, each unit of currency buys fewer goods and services; consequently, inflation corresponds to a reductio ...
, or GDP. There are several policy implications of multiplier uncertainty: (1) If the multiplier uncertainty is
uncorrelated In probability theory and statistics, two real-valued random variables, X, Y, are said to be uncorrelated if their covariance, \operatorname ,Y= \operatorname Y- \operatorname \operatorname /math>, is zero. If two variables are uncorrelated, ther ...
with additive uncertainty, its presence causes greater cautiousness to be optimal (the policy tools should be used to a lesser extent). (2) In the presence of multiplier uncertainty, it is no longer redundant to have more policy tools than there are targeted economic variables. (3)
Certainty equivalence Stochastic control or stochastic optimal control is a sub field of control theory that deals with the existence of uncertainty either in observations or in the noise that drives the evolution of the system. The system designer assumes, in a Bayesi ...
no longer applies under quadratic
loss Loss may refer to: Arts, entertainment, and media Music * ''Loss'' (Bass Communion album) (2006) * ''Loss'' (Mull Historical Society album) (2001) *"Loss", a song by God Is an Astronaut from their self-titled album (2008) * Losses "(Lil Tjay son ...
: optimal policy is not equivalent to a policy of ignoring uncertainty.


Effect of multiplier uncertainty on the optimal magnitude of policy

For the simplest possible case, let ''P'' be the size of a policy action (a government spending change, for example), let ''y'' be the value of the target variable (GDP for example), let ''a'' be the policy multiplier, and let ''u'' be an additive term capturing both the linear intercept and all unpredictable components of the determination of ''y''. Both ''a'' and ''u'' are random variables (assumed here for simplicity to be uncorrelated), with respective means E''a'' and E''u'' and respective variances \sigma^2_a and \sigma^2_u. Then :y = aP + u. Suppose the policy maker cares about the expected squared deviation of GDP from a preferred value y_d; then its loss function ''L'' is quadratic so that the objective function, expected loss, is given by: :\textL = \text(y-y_d)^2 = \text(aP + u - y_d)^2 = text(aP + u - y_d)2 + \text (aP + u - y_d) = \texta)P + \textu - y_d2 + P^2 \sigma^2_a + \sigma^2_u. where the last equality assumes there is no covariance between ''a'' and ''u''. Optimizing with respect to the policy variable ''P'' gives the optimal value ''P''''opt'': :P^ = \frac. Here the last term in the numerator is the gap between the preferred value ''y''''d'' of the target variable and its expected value E''u'' in the absence of any policy action. If there were no uncertainty about the policy multiplier, \sigma^2_a would be zero, and policy would be chosen so that the contribution of policy (the policy action ''P'' times its known multiplier ''a'') would be to exactly close this gap, so that with the policy action E''y'' would equal ''y''''d''. However, the optimal policy equation shows that, to the extent that there is multiplier uncertainty (the extent to which \sigma^2_a > 0), the magnitude of the optimal policy action is diminished. Thus the basic effect of multiplier uncertainty is to make policy actions more cautious, although this effect can be modified in more complicated models.


Multiple targets or policy instruments

The above analysis of one target variable and one policy tool can readily be extended to multiple targets and tools. In this case a key result is that, unlike in the absence of multiplier uncertainty, it is not superfluous to have more policy tools than targets: with multiplier uncertainty, the more tools are available the lower expected loss can be driven.


Analogy to portfolio theory

There is a mathematical and conceptual analogy between, on the one hand, policy optimization with multiple policy tools having multiplier uncertainty, and on the other hand,
portfolio optimization Portfolio optimization is the process of selecting the best portfolio (asset distribution), out of the set of all portfolios being considered, according to some objective. The objective typically maximizes factors such as expected return, and minimi ...
involving multiple investment choices having rate-of-return uncertainty. The usages of the policy variables correspond to the holdings of the risky assets, and the uncertain policy multipliers correspond to the uncertain rates of return on the assets. In both models, mutual fund theorems apply: under certain conditions, the optimal portfolios of all investors regardless of their preferences, or the optimal policy mixes of all policy makers regardless of their preferences, can be expressed as linear combinations of any two optimal portfolios or optimal policy mixes.


Dynamic policy optimization

The above discussion assumed a static world in which policy actions and outcomes for only one moment in time were considered. However, the analysis generalizes to a context of multiple time periods in which both policy actions take place and target variable outcomes matter, and in which time lags in the effects of policy actions exist. In this dynamic stochastic control context with multiplier uncertainty, a key result is that the "certainty equivalence principle" does not apply: while in the absence of multiplier uncertainty (that is, with only additive uncertainty) the optimal policy with a quadratic loss function coincides with what would be decided if the uncertainty were ignored, this no longer holds in the presence of multiplier uncertainty.


References

{{reflist Macroeconomic policy Stochastic control