José Encarnación Jr.
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

José Encarnación Jr. (November 17, 1928 – July 5, 1998) was a Filipino professor of economics at the
University of the Philippines Diliman The University of the Philippines Diliman (also called UPD; ), also referred to as UP Diliman, is a State university and college (Philippines), public, coeducational, Research university, research university located in Diliman, Quezon City, Ph ...
, where he served as
dean Dean may refer to: People * Dean (given name) * Dean (surname), a surname of Anglo-Saxon English origin * Dean (South Korean singer), a stage name for singer Kwon Hyuk * Dean Delannoit, a Belgian singer most known by the mononym Dean * Dean Sw ...
of the School of Economics from 1974 until his retirement in 1994.


Education

Encarnación was educated at UP Diliman (PhB, MA Philosophy) and at
Princeton University Princeton University is a private university, private Ivy League research university in Princeton, New Jersey, United States. Founded in 1746 in Elizabeth, New Jersey, Elizabeth as the College of New Jersey, Princeton is the List of Colonial ...
(PhD Economics). He was a fellow of the
Upsilon Sigma Phi The Upsilon Sigma Phi () is the oldest Greek-letter organization and fraternity in Asia. Founded in 1918, it is also the oldest student organization in continuous existence in the University of the Philippines. It has two chapters—an integra ...
fraternity. At Princeton he was a student and dissertation advisee of William J. Baumol. The only Filipino economist of his generation to work in the field of theory, Encarnación was best known for advancing the theory of
lexicographic preferences In economics, lexicographic preferences or lexicographic orderings describe comparative preferences where an agent prefers any amount of one good (X) to any amount of another (Y). Specifically, if offered several bundles of goods, the agent will c ...
, which in the words of Richard Day, Encarnación "almost singlehandedly kept alive". In 1963, he was accorded as a member of the Ten Outstanding Young Men (TOYM) Awardee for Economics. In 1987 he was named National Scientist, the highest recognition of scientific achievement given by the
Republic of the Philippines The Philippines, officially the Republic of the Philippines, is an archipelagic country in Southeast Asia. Located in the western Pacific Ocean, it consists of 7,641 islands, with a total area of roughly 300,000 square kilometers, which ar ...
.E. S. de Dios and R. V. Fabella (eds.)
997 Year 997 ( CMXCVII) was a common year starting on Friday of the Julian calendar. Events By place Japan * 1 February: Empress Teishi gives birth to Princess Shushi - she is the first child of the emperor, but because of the power stru ...
''Choice, growth, and development: emerging and enduring issues. Essays in honor of José Encarnación Jr''.
University of the Philippines The University of the Philippines (UP; ) is a Higher education in the Philippines#State universities and colleges, state university system in the Philippines. It is the country's national university, as mandated by List of Philippine laws, Re ...
Press
In 2008, the main building of the School of Economics at the University of the Philippines was renamed Encarnación Hall in his honor.


Major contributions

Source:


Lexicographic preferences

Lexicographic preferences In economics, lexicographic preferences or lexicographic orderings describe comparative preferences where an agent prefers any amount of one good (X) to any amount of another (Y). Specifically, if offered several bundles of goods, the agent will c ...
map a set of alternatives ''X'' onto a set of vectors, for which reason lexicographic preferences are also known as vector-valued preferences. (A mapping onto the set of real numbers instead yields real-valued utility.) Formally one posits a mapping ''V'': ''X''→ ''Rn'', where ''n'' refers to the arbitrarily many or few dimensions of the vector and corresponds to the number of criteria of choice. Hence, let the vector ''v''(''x'') = 'v''1(''x''), ''v''2(''x''),…represent the scores ''vi''(''x'') of an alternative ''x'' on various characteristics or criteria ''i'' = 1,2,…., arranged in decreasing order of importance. Define ''v''(''y'') similarly. Then ''x'' is better than ''y'' if the first nonzero component of the vector difference ''v''(''x'')- ''v''(''y'') is positive. The term ''lexicographic'' refers to the fact that dictionaries similarly order words by their successive components, i.e. letters.


L*-ordering

One disadvantage of simple lexicographic ordering as described above is that subsequent criteria come into consideration only when the objects being compared are tied with respect to the preceding criteria. For example, in choosing a restaurant, price, cuisine quality, and ambience may be considerations, in decreasing order. Under simple lexicographic ordering, among all restaurants with the same price, those with the best cuisine would be preferred. And among those with the same price and the same quality of cuisine, the one with the best ambience would be chosen. These further criteria would be irrelevant, however, if there was a unique restaurant with the lowest price, since this one would always be preferred to more expensive ones, no matter how bad their cuisine or ambience. This is the implication of making price the first criterion. Such a prediction is obviously unrealistic, however, and it is closer to experience to say that people have minimum acceptable levels or “thresholds” for certain criteria. The process of selecting a restaurant, for example, involves a continual process of narrowing down one’s choice by the application of successive criteria. First, restaurants where a meal per head does not exceed a certain price; from among those that pass that criterion, those whose quality of cuisine falls no lower than a specified level; then finally from those that pass the two previous criteria, those whose atmosphere is best. It is this process that Encarnación formalized in 1964. If ''ui''(''x'') represents the degree of achievement in criterion ''i'' when in possession of ''x'', a threshold level ''ui''* may be defined corresponding to a ''satisficing'' or satisfactory level of that criterion. The novel idea is that further increases in the value of ''ui'' beyond ''ui''* do not matter. The importance of an alternative ''x'' with respect to the ''i''th criterion may then be written as ''vi''(''x'') = min(''ui''(''x''),''ui''*). Hence, ordering wants or criteria in decreasing order of importance, define the vector ''v''(''x'') = 'v''1(''x''), ''v''2(''x''),… Then in the now-familiar vector comparison, ''x'' is preferred to ''y'' if and only if the first nonzero component of the vector difference ''v''(''x'') - ''v''(''y'') is positive. This revised lexicographic ordering incorporating thresholds, with which Encarnacion’s name has become inextricable, has since become known as an ''L* ordering'' to distinguish it from the ordinary lexicographic, or L-ordering.


L*-orderings under uncertainty

Lexicographic preferences have also been found useful in describing choices under uncertainty. Let ''wi'' = ''wi''(''x'', ''p''(''x'')) be the ''i''th utility from a vector of prospects ''x'' = (''x''1,…, ''xk'',…) which has associated probabilities ''p''(''x'') = (''p''1(''x1''),…,''pk''(''xn'')). Note that the criterion function ''wi'' depends explicitly not only on ''x'' but also on the probabilities associated with ''x''. One may then define ''w¡''* as the satisficing level of ''w¡'' and proceed to define lexicographic preference in the customary manner, with ''v''(''x'') = 'v''1(''x''),''v''2(x),…and ''v''i(''x'') = min (''wi'' (''x'', ''p''(x), ''wi''*) for all ''i''. It is straightforward to reproduce expected utility as a particular case by defining some primitive utility function ''u''(.) that depends only on the individual ''xk''. In this case, one may write ''w''1(''x'', ''p''(''x'')•''u''(''x'')), where ''u''(''x'') = 'u''(''x''1), ''u''(''x''2),…and set ''w''1* sufficiently high to obtain the usual subjective expected utility. If other criteria are allowed to come into play, on the other hand, different possibilities arise. For example, for some ''i'', ''wi'' may depend only on the probability of ruinous levels of ''x'', or on the maximal values of ''x''. Encarnación 987ref>"Preferences paradoxes and lexicographic choice", ''Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization'' 8(2):231-248 uses preferences of this form in an ambitious attempt to reconstruct and explain all the apparent “paradoxes” in choice theory. Apart from lexicographic comparisons the new element introduced into the structure was the notion of significant differences in the values of criterion functions. Choice between two uncertain alternatives x and y, he suggests, turns on whether they differ significantly on the following lexicographically arranged criteria: (1) expected value, (2) the possibility of a large loss, (3) the possibility of maximal gain, and finally (4) expected value once more. Unlike his earlier 1964 formulation, however, this later version allows for intransitivity.


References


External links

* https://web.archive.org/web/20120321214712/http://www.nast.ph/index.php?option=com_profile&id=79&view=details&template=nast3 * https://web.archive.org/web/20111003180749/http://www.econ.upd.edu.ph/je/ {{DEFAULTSORT:Encarnacion, Jose Jr. 1928 births 1998 deaths Academic staff of the University of the Philippines Princeton University alumni 20th-century Filipino economists University of the Philippines Diliman alumni National Scientists of the Philippines Burials at the Libingan ng mga Bayani