Cobb–Douglas Production Function
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

In
economics Economics () is a behavioral science that studies the Production (economics), production, distribution (economics), distribution, and Consumption (economics), consumption of goods and services. Economics focuses on the behaviour and interac ...
and
econometrics Econometrics is an application of statistical methods to economic data in order to give empirical content to economic relationships. M. Hashem Pesaran (1987). "Econometrics", '' The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics'', v. 2, p. 8 p. 8 ...
, the Cobb–Douglas production function is a particular functional form of the
production function In economics, a production function gives the technological relation between quantities of physical inputs and quantities of output of goods. The production function is one of the key concepts of mainstream economics, mainstream neoclassical econ ...
, widely used to represent the technological relationship between the amounts of two or more inputs (particularly physical capital and labor) and the amount of output that can be produced by those inputs. The Cobb–Douglas form was developed and tested against statistical evidence by Charles Cobb and Paul Douglas between 1927 and 1947; according to Douglas, the functional form itself was developed earlier by
Philip Wicksteed Philip Henry Wicksteed (25 October 1844 – 18 March 1927) was an English scholar and Unitarian theologian known for his contributions to classics, medieval studies and economics. He was also a Georgist and literary critic. Family background ...
.


Formulation

In its most standard form for production of a single good with two factors, the function is given by: : Y(L,K)=AL^\beta K^\alpha where: * ''Y'' = total production (the real value of all goods produced in a year or 365.25 days) * ''L'' = labour input (person-hours worked in a year or 365.25 days) * ''K'' = capital input (a measure of all machinery, equipment, and buildings; the value of capital input divided by the price of capital) * ''A'' =
total factor productivity In economics, total-factor productivity (TFP), also called multi-factor productivity, is usually measured as the ratio of aggregate output (e.g., GDP) to aggregate inputs. Under some simplifying assumptions about the production technology, growt ...
* 0<\alpha<1 and 0<\beta<1 are the output elasticities of capital and labor, respectively. These values are constants determined by available technology. Capital and labour are the two "factors of production" of the Cobb–Douglas production function.


History

Paul Douglas explained that his first formulation of the Cobb–Douglas production function was developed in 1927; when seeking a functional form to relate estimates he had calculated for workers and capital, he spoke with mathematician and colleague Charles Cobb, who suggested a function of the form , previously used by
Knut Wicksell Johan Gustaf Knut Wicksell (December 20, 1851 – May 3, 1926) was a Swedish economist of the Stockholm school. He was professor at Uppsala University and Lund University. He made contributions to theories of population, value, capital and mon ...
,
Philip Wicksteed Philip Henry Wicksteed (25 October 1844 – 18 March 1927) was an English scholar and Unitarian theologian known for his contributions to classics, medieval studies and economics. He was also a Georgist and literary critic. Family background ...
, and
Léon Walras Marie-Esprit-Léon Walras (; 16 December 1834 – 5 January 1910) was a French mathematical economics, mathematical economist and Georgist. He formulated the Marginalism, marginal theory of value (independently of William Stanley Jevons and Carl ...
, although Douglas only acknowledges Wicksteed and Walras for their contributions. Not long after
Knut Wicksell Johan Gustaf Knut Wicksell (December 20, 1851 – May 3, 1926) was a Swedish economist of the Stockholm school. He was professor at Uppsala University and Lund University. He made contributions to theories of population, value, capital and mon ...
's death in 1926, Paul Douglas and Charles Cobb implemented the Cobb–Douglas function in their work covering the subject manner of producer theory for the first time. Estimating this using
least squares The method of least squares is a mathematical optimization technique that aims to determine the best fit function by minimizing the sum of the squares of the differences between the observed values and the predicted values of the model. The me ...
, he obtained a result for the exponent of labour of 0.75—which was subsequently confirmed by the
National Bureau of Economic Research The National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) is an American private nonprofit research organization "committed to undertaking and disseminating unbiased economic research among public policymakers, business professionals, and the academic co ...
to be 0.741. Later work in the 1940s prompted them to allow for the exponents on ''K'' and ''L'' to vary, resulting in estimates that subsequently proved to be very close to improved measure of productivity developed at that time. A major criticism at the time was that estimates of the production function, although seemingly accurate, were based on such sparse data that it was hard to give them much credibility. Douglas remarked "I must admit I was discouraged by this criticism and thought of giving up the effort, but there was something which told me I should hold on." The breakthrough came in using US census data, which was cross-sectional and provided a large number of observations. Douglas presented the results of these findings, along with those for other countries, at his 1947 address as president of the
American Economic Association The American Economic Association (AEA) is a learned society in the field of economics, with approximately 23,000 members. It publishes several peer-reviewed journals, including the Journal of Economic Literature, American Economic Review, an ...
. Shortly afterwards, Douglas went into politics and was stricken by ill health—resulting in little further development on his side. However, two decades later, his production function was widely used, being adopted by economists such as
Paul Samuelson Paul Anthony Samuelson (May 15, 1915 – December 13, 2009) was an American economist who was the first American to win the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences. When awarding the prize in 1970, the Swedish Royal Academies stated that he "h ...
and
Robert Solow Robert Merton Solow, GCIH (; August 23, 1924 – December 21, 2023) was an American economist who received the 1987 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences, and whose work on the theory of economic growth culminated in the exogenous growth ...
. The Cobb–Douglas production function is especially notable for being the first time an aggregate or economy-wide production function had been developed, estimated, and then presented to the profession for analysis; it marked a landmark change in how economists approached macroeconomics from a microeconomics perspective.


Positivity of marginal products

The marginal product of a factor of production is the change in output when that factor of production changes, holding constant all the other factors of production as well as the total factor productivity. The marginal product of capital, MPK corresponds to the first derivative of the production function with respect to capital: : MPK=\frac = \alpha A L^\beta K^ = \alpha \frac = \alpha \frac Because \alpha>0 (and Y>0, K>0 as well), we find out that the marginal product of capital is always positive; that is, increasing capital leads to an increase in output. We also find that increasing the total factor productivity A increases the marginal product of capital. An analogous reasoning holds for labor.


Law of diminishing returns

Taking the derivative of the marginal product of capital with respect to capital (i.e., taking the second derivative of the production function with respect to capital), we have: : \frac = \frac = \frac ( A L^\beta \alpha K^ ) = A L^\beta \alpha (\alpha-1) K^ = \alpha (\alpha-1) A L^\beta \frac = \alpha (\alpha-1) \frac Because \alpha<1, then \alpha-1<0 and so \dfrac<0. Thus, this function satisfies the law of "diminishing returns"; that is, the marginal product of capital, while always positive, is declining. As capital increases (holding labor and total factor productivity constant), the output increases but at a diminishing rate. A similar reasoning holds for labor.


Cross derivatives

We can study what happens to the marginal product of capital when labor increases by taking the partial derivative of the marginal product of capital with respect to labor, that is, the cross-derivative of output with respect to capital and labor: \dfrac = \dfrac = \dfrac ( A L^\beta \alpha K^ ) = A \beta L^ \alpha K^ = A \alpha \beta \dfrac = \alpha \beta \dfrac Since \dfrac>0, an increase in labor raises the marginal product of capital.


Returns to scale

Output elasticity measures the responsiveness of output to a change in levels of either labor or capital used in production,
ceteris paribus ' (also spelled ') (Classical ) is a Latin phrase, meaning "other things equal"; some other English translations of the phrase are "all other things being equal", "other things held constant", "all else unchanged", and "all else being equal". ...
. For example, if , a increase in capital usage would lead to approximately a increase in output. Sometimes the term has a more restricted meaning, requiring that the function display
constant returns to scale In economics, the concept of returns to scale arises in the context of a firm's production function. It explains the long-run linkage of increase in output (production) relative to associated increases in the inputs (factors of production). In th ...
, meaning that increasing capital ''K'' and labor ''L'' by a factor ''k'' also increases output ''Y'' by the same factor, that is, Y(kL,kK)=kY(L,K). This holds if \alpha+\beta=1. If \alpha+\beta<1, then returns to scale are decreasing, meaning that an increase of capital ''K'' and labor ''L'' by a factor ''k'' will produce an increase in output ''Y'' smaller than a factor ''k'', that is Y(kL,kK). If \alpha+\beta>1, then returns to scale are increasing, meaning that an increase in capital ''K'' and labor ''L'' by a factor ''k'' produce an increase in output ''Y'' greater than a factor ''k'', that is, Y(kL,kK)>kY(L,K).


Remuneration under perfect competition

Under
perfect competition In economics, specifically general equilibrium theory, a perfect market, also known as an atomistic market, is defined by several idealizing conditions, collectively called perfect competition, or atomistic competition. In Economic model, theoret ...
, the factors of production are remunerated at their total marginal product. Suppose that Y=F(L,K) = L^\alpha K^ where 0<\alpha<1. In this case MP_L=\alpha L^ K^ = \alpha (\frac) ^ and MP_K=(1-\alpha) L^ K^ = (1-\alpha) (\frac) ^ . Therefore, Y=L\cdot MP_L + K\cdot MP_K = \alpha L^\alpha K^ + (1-\alpha)L^\alpha K^ . Dividing both sides by Y=F(L,K) = L^\alpha K^ we obtain that the remuneration of labor is \alpha of the production and the remuneration of capital is (1-\alpha) of the production. Let us normalize the price of Y to 1. In a competitive equilibrium the value of marginal product of a production factor equals its price or P_Y\cdot MP_K = MP_K=w and similarly MP_K= r where w is the wage rate and r is the price of capital, the
real interest rate The real interest rate is the rate of interest an investor, saver or lender receives (or expects to receive) after allowing for inflation. It can be described more formally by the Fisher equation, which states that the real interest rate is appro ...
(assuming that capital fully depreciates after one period, otherwise, the price of capital is r+\delta where \delta is the depreciation rate of capital). The total production can be written as follows: Y=L\cdot w + K\cdot r . That is, the value of production is divides between renumeration for labor and renumeration for capital.


Generalized form

In its generalized form, the Cobb–Douglas function models more than two goods. The Cobb–Douglas function may be written as :f(x)=A \prod_^n x_i^, \qquad x = (x_1, \ldots, x_n). where * ''A'' is an efficiency parameter * ''n'' is the total number of input variables (goods) * are the (non-negative) quantities of good consumed, produced, etc. * \lambda_i is an elasticity parameter for good ''i''


Criticisms

The function has been criticised for its lack of foundation. Cobb and Douglas were influenced by statistical evidence that appeared to show that labor and capital shares of total output were constant over time in developed countries; they explained this by statistical fitting least-squares regression of their production function. It is now widely accepted that labor share is declining in industrialized economies. The production function contains a principal assumption that may not always provide the most accurate representation of a country's productive capabilities and supply-side efficiencies. This assumption is a "constant share of labor in output," which may not be effective when applied to cases of countries whose labor markets are growing at significant rates. Another issue within the fundamental composition the Cobb–Douglas production function is the presence of simultaneous equation bias. When competition is presumed, the simultaneous equation bias has impact on all function types involving firm decisions – including the Cobb–Douglas function. In some cases this simultaneous equation bias doesn't appear. However, it is apparent when least squares asymptotic approximations are used. The Cobb–Douglas production function was not developed on the basis of any knowledge of engineering, technology, or management of the production process. This rationale may be true given the definition of the Capital term. Labor hours and Capital need a better definition. If capital is defined as a building, labor is already included in the development of that building. A building is composed of commodities, labor and risks and general conditions. It was instead developed because it had attractive mathematical characteristics, such as diminishing marginal returns to either factor of production and the property that the optimal expenditure shares on any given input of a firm operating a Cobb–Douglas technology are constant. Initially, there were no utility foundations for it. In the modern era, some economists try to build models up from individual agents acting, rather than imposing a functional form on an entire economy. The Cobb–Douglas production function, if properly defined, can be applied at a micro-economic level, up to a macro- economic level. However, many modern authors have developed models which give microeconomically based Cobb–Douglas production functions, including many
New Keynesian New Keynesian economics is a school of macroeconomics that strives to provide microeconomic foundations for Keynesian economics. It developed partly as a response to criticisms of Keynesian macroeconomics by adherents of new classical macroe ...
models. It is nevertheless a mathematical mistake to assume that just because the Cobb–Douglas function applies at the microeconomic level, it also always applies at the
macroeconomic Macroeconomics is a branch of economics that deals with the performance, structure, behavior, and decision-making of an economy as a whole. This includes regional, national, and global economies. Macroeconomists study topics such as output/ GDP ...
level. Similarly, it is not necessarily the case that a macro Cobb–Douglas applies at the disaggregated level. An early microfoundation of the aggregate Cobb–Douglas technology based on linear activities is derived in Houthakker (1955). The Cobb–Douglas production function is inconsistent with modern empirical estimates of the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor, which suggest that capital and labor are gross complements. A 2021 meta-analysis of 3186 estimates concludes that "the weight of evidence accumulated in the empirical literature emphatically rejects the Cobb–Douglas specification."


Cobb–Douglas utilities

The Cobb–Douglas function is often used as a
utility function In economics, utility is a measure of a certain person's satisfaction from a certain state of the world. Over time, the term has been used with at least two meanings. * In a Normative economics, normative context, utility refers to a goal or ob ...
. Utility \tilde is a function of the quantities x_i of the n goods consumed: : \tilde(x)= \prod_^n x_i^ Utility functions represent ordinal preferences and do not have natural units, unlike production functions. As the result, a monotonic transformation of a utility function represents the same preferences. Unlike with a Cobb–Douglas production function, where the sum of the exponents determines the degree of
economies of scale In microeconomics, economies of scale are the cost advantages that enterprises obtain due to their scale of operation, and are typically measured by the amount of Productivity, output produced per unit of cost (production cost). A decrease in ...
, the sum can be normalized to one for a utility function because normalization is a monotonic transformation of the original utility function. Thus, let us define \lambda = \sum_^n \lambda_i and \alpha_i = \frac, so \sum_^n \alpha_i = 1, and write the utility function as: :u(x) = \prod_^n x_i^ The consumer maximizes utility subject to the budget constraint that the cost of the goods is less than her wealth w. Letting p_i denote the goods' prices, she solves: : \max_ \prod_^n x_i^ \quad \text \quad \sum_^n p_i x_i= w :The
Marginal Rate of Substitution In economics, the marginal rate of substitution (MRS) is the rate at which a consumer can give up some amount of one good in exchange for another good while maintaining the same level of utility. At equilibrium consumption levels (assuming no ext ...
between each two goods is :MRS_=\frac=\Rightarrow p_j x_j=x_i :By inserting to the budget constrain we obtain : :p_i x_i + \textstyle \sum_^n \displaystyle p_j x_j \frac = w :\Rightarrow p_i x_i(1+\sum_^n \frac)=w \Rightarrow p_i x_i\frac =w \Rightarrow p_i x_i\frac =w :\Rightarrow x_i^*=\frac \forall i : Note that p_i x^*_i = \alpha_i w , the consumer spends fraction \alpha_i of her wealth on good . Also note that each good is affected solely by its own price. That is, any two goods are not substitute goods nor complementary goods. Namely, their cross elasticity equals to zero and the cross demand function of any good is described by a vertical line. Finally, note that when the income increase by some percent the demand for the good increase by the same percent. That is, the elasticity of the demand with respect to income equals 1 and therefore, the Engel curve is a straight line starting from the origin. Note that this is the solution for either u(x) or \tilde(x), since the same preferences generate the same demand. The indirect utility function can be calculated by substituting the demands x_i into the utility function. Define the constant K= \prod_^n \alpha_i^ and we get: : v(p,w) = \prod_^n \left( \frac \right)^ = \frac =K \left(\frac \right) which is a special case of the Gorman polar form. The expenditure function is the inverse of the indirect utility function: :e(p, u) = (1/K)\prod_^n p_i^ u :The Marshallian demand function that Cobb-Douglas utility function


Various representations of the production function

The Cobb–Douglas function form can be estimated as a linear relationship using the following expression: : \ln(Y) = a_0 + \sum_i a_i \ln(I_i) where * Y = \text * I_i = \text * a_i = \text The model can also be written as : Y = e^ (I_1)^ \cdot (I_2)^ \cdots As noted, the common Cobb–Douglas function used in macroeconomic modeling is : Y = K^\alpha L^\beta where ''K'' is capital and ''L'' is labor. When the model exponents sum to one, the production function is first-order
homogeneous Homogeneity and heterogeneity are concepts relating to the uniformity of a substance, process or image. A homogeneous feature is uniform in composition or character (i.e., color, shape, size, weight, height, distribution, texture, language, i ...
, which implies constant returns to scale—that is, if all inputs are scaled by a common factor greater than zero, output will be scaled by the same factor.


Relationship to the CES production function

The
constant elasticity of substitution Constant elasticity of substitution (CES) is a common specification of many production functions and utility function In economics, utility is a measure of a certain person's satisfaction from a certain state of the world. Over time, the term ...
(CES) production function (in the two-factor case) is : Y = A \left ( \alpha K^\gamma + (1-\alpha) L^\gamma \right )^, in which the limiting case corresponds to a Cobb–Douglas function, Y=AK^\alpha L^, with constant returns to scale. To see this, the log of the CES function: : \ln(Y) = \ln(A) + \frac \ln \left (\alpha K^\gamma + (1-\alpha) L^\gamma \right ) can be taken to the limit by applying
L'Hôpital's rule L'Hôpital's rule (, ), also known as Bernoulli's rule, is a mathematical theorem that allows evaluating limits of indeterminate forms using derivatives. Application (or repeated application) of the rule often converts an indeterminate form ...
: : \lim_ \ln(Y) = \ln(A) + \alpha \ln(K) + (1-\alpha) \ln(L). Therefore, Y=AK^\alpha L^.


Translog production function

The translog production function is an approximation of the CES function by a second-order Taylor polynomial in the variable \gamma about \gamma = 0, i.e. the Cobb–Douglas case. The name translog stands for "transcendental logarithmic." It is often used in
econometrics Econometrics is an application of statistical methods to economic data in order to give empirical content to economic relationships. M. Hashem Pesaran (1987). "Econometrics", '' The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics'', v. 2, p. 8 p. 8 ...
for the fact that it is linear in the parameters, which means
ordinary least squares In statistics, ordinary least squares (OLS) is a type of linear least squares method for choosing the unknown parameters in a linear regression In statistics, linear regression is a statistical model, model that estimates the relationship ...
could be used if inputs could be assumed exogenous. In the two-factor case above the translog production function is : \begin \ln(Y) &= \ln(A) + \alpha \ln(K) + (1-\alpha) \ln(L) + \frac \gamma \alpha (1 - \alpha) \left \ln(K) - \ln(L) \right2 \\ &= \ln(A) + a_K \ln(K) + a_L \ln(L) + b_ \ln^2(K) + b_ \ln^(L) + b_ \ln(K) \ln(L) \end where a_K, a_L, b_, b_, and b_ are defined appropriately. In the three factor case, the translog production function is: :\begin \ln(Y) & = \ln(A) + a_L\ln(L) + a_K\ln(K) + a_M\ln(M) + b_\ln^2(L) +b_\ln^2(K) + b_\ln^2(M) \\ & \qquad \qquad + b_\ln(L)\ln(K) + b_\ln(L)\ln(M) + b_\ln(K)\ln(M) \\ & = f(L,K,M). \end where A = total factor productivity, L = labor, K = capital, M = materials and supplies, and Y = output.


See also

*
Leontief production function In economics, the Leontief production function or fixed proportions production function is a production function that implies the factors of production which will be used in fixed (technologically predetermined) proportions, as there is no substi ...
*
Production–possibility frontier In microeconomics, a production–possibility frontier (PPF), production possibility curve (PPC), or production possibility boundary (PPB) is a graphical representation showing all the possible quantities of outputs that can be Production (econom ...
* Production theory


References


Further reading

*


External links


Anatomy of Cobb–Douglas Type Production Functions in 3D

Analysis of the Cobb–Douglas as a utility function

Closed Form Solution for a firm with an N-input production function
{{DEFAULTSORT:Cobb-Douglas production function Utility function types 1947 in economic history Production economics