Classical economics, classical political economy, or Smithian economics is a
school of thought in
political economy that flourished, primarily in
Britain, in the late 18th and early-to-mid 19th century. Its main thinkers are held to be
Adam Smith
Adam Smith (baptized 1723 – 17 July 1790) was a Scottish economist and philosopher who was a pioneer in the thinking of political economy and key figure during the Scottish Enlightenment. Seen by some as "The Father of Economics"——— ...
,
Jean-Baptiste Say
Jean-Baptiste Say (; 5 January 1767 – 15 November 1832) was a liberal French economist and businessman who argued in favor of competition, free trade and lifting restraints on business. He is best known for Say's law—also known as the law of ...
,
David Ricardo,
Thomas Robert Malthus, and
John Stuart Mill
John Stuart Mill (20 May 1806 – 7 May 1873) was an English philosopher, political economist, Member of Parliament (MP) and civil servant. One of the most influential thinkers in the history of classical liberalism, he contributed widely to ...
. These economists produced a theory of
market economies as largely self-regulating systems, governed by natural laws of production and exchange (famously captured by Adam Smith's metaphor of the
invisible hand).
Adam Smith's ''
The Wealth of Nations'' in 1776 is usually considered to mark the beginning of classical economics.
[Smith, Adam (1776) An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of The Wealth of Nations. (accessible by table of contents chapter titles) AdamSmith.org ] The fundamental message in Smith's book was that the wealth of any nation was determined not by the gold in the monarch's coffers, but by its national income. This income was in turn based on the labor of its inhabitants, organized efficiently by the
division of labour
The division of labour is the separation of the tasks in any economic system or organisation so that participants may specialise (specialisation). Individuals, organizations, and nations are endowed with, or acquire specialised capabilities, and ...
and the use of accumulated
capital
Capital may refer to:
Common uses
* Capital city, a municipality of primary status
** List of national capital cities
* Capital letter, an upper-case letter Economics and social sciences
* Capital (economics), the durable produced goods used f ...
, which became one of classical economics' central concepts.
In terms of economic policy, the classical economists were pragmatic
liberals, advocating the freedom of the market, though they saw a role for the state in providing for the
common good. Smith acknowledged that there were areas where the market is not the best way to serve the common interest, and he took it as a given that the greater proportion of the costs supporting the common good should be borne by those best able to afford them. He warned repeatedly of the dangers of monopoly, and stressed the importance of competition.
In terms of
international trade, the classical economists were advocates of
free trade, which distinguishes them from their
mercantilist predecessors, who advocated
protectionism.
The designation of Smith, Ricardo and some earlier economists as "classical" is due to a canonization which stems from
Karl Marx's
critique of political economy, where he critiqued those that he at least perceived as worthy of dealing with, as opposed to their "vulgar" successors. There is some
debate about what is covered by the term ''classical economics'', particularly when dealing with the period from 1830 to 1875, and how classical economics relates to
neoclassical economics.
History
The classical economists produced their "magnificent dynamics"
[Baumol, William J. (1970) ''Economic Dynamics'', 3rd edition, Macmillan (as cited in Caravale, Giovanni A. and Domenico A. Tosato (1980) ''Ricardo and the Theory of Value, Distribution and Growth'', Routledge & Kegan Paul)] during a period in which
capitalism was emerging from
feudalism and in which the
Industrial Revolution was leading to vast changes in society. These changes raised the question of how a society could be organized around a system in which every individual sought his or her own (monetary) gain. Classical political economy is popularly associated with the idea that free markets can regulate themselves.
Classical economists and their immediate predecessors reoriented economics away from an analysis of the ruler's personal interests to broader national interests.
Adam Smith
Adam Smith (baptized 1723 – 17 July 1790) was a Scottish economist and philosopher who was a pioneer in the thinking of political economy and key figure during the Scottish Enlightenment. Seen by some as "The Father of Economics"——— ...
, following the
physiocrat François Quesnay
François Quesnay (; 4 June 1694 – 16 December 1774) was a French economist and physician of the Physiocratic school. He is known for publishing the "Tableau économique" (Economic Table) in 1758, which provided the foundations of the ideas of ...
, identified the wealth of a nation with the yearly national income, instead of the king's treasury. Smith saw this income as produced by labour, land, and capital. With property rights to land and capital held by individuals, the national income is divided up between labourers, landlords, and capitalists in the form of
wages
A wage is payment made by an employer to an employee for work done in a specific period of time. Some examples of wage payments include compensatory payments such as ''minimum wage'', ''prevailing wage'', and ''yearly bonuses,'' and remuner ...
,
rent, and
interest or profits. In his vision,
productive labour was the true source of income, while capital was the main organizing force, boosting labour's productivity and inducing
growth.
Ricardo and
James Mill systematized Smith's theory. Their ideas became economic orthodoxy in the period ca. 1815–1848, after which an "anti-Ricardian reaction" took shape, especially on the European continent, that eventually became
marginalist/neoclassical economics. The definitive split is typically placed somewhere in the 1870s, after which the torch of Ricardian economics was carried mainly by
Marxian economics
Marxian economics, or the Marxian school of economics, is a Heterodox economics, heterodox school of political economic thought. Its foundations can be traced back to Karl Marx, Karl Marx's Critique of political economy#Marx's critique of politic ...
, while neoclassical economics became the new orthodoxy also in the English-speaking world.
Henry George is sometimes known as the last classical economist or as a bridge. The economist
Mason Gaffney
Merrill Mason Gaffney (October 18, 1923 – July 16, 2020) was an American economist and a major critic of Neoclassical economics from a Georgist point of view. Gaffney first read Henry George's masterwork '' Progress and Poverty'' as a high sch ...
documented original sources that appear to confirm his thesis arguing that
neoclassical economics arose as a concerted effort to suppress the ideas of classical economics and those of Henry George in particular.
Modern legacy
Classical economics and many of its ideas remain fundamental in economics, though the theory itself has yielded, since the 1870s, to neoclassical economics. Other ideas have either disappeared from neoclassical discourse or been replaced by
Keynesian economics in the
Keynesian Revolution and
neoclassical synthesis
The neoclassical synthesis (NCS), neoclassical–Keynesian synthesis, or just neo-Keynesianism was a neoclassical economics academic movement and paradigm in economics that worked towards reconciling the macroeconomic thought of John Maynard Key ...
. Some classical ideas are represented in various schools of
heterodox economics
Heterodox economics is any economic thought or theory that contrasts with orthodox schools of economic thought, or that may be beyond neoclassical economics.Frederic S. Lee, 2008. "heterodox economics," ''The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics' ...
, notably
Georgism and
Marxian economics
Marxian economics, or the Marxian school of economics, is a Heterodox economics, heterodox school of political economic thought. Its foundations can be traced back to Karl Marx, Karl Marx's Critique of political economy#Marx's critique of politic ...
– Marx and
Henry George being contemporaries of classical economists – and
Austrian economics, which split from neoclassical economics in the late 19th century. In the mid-20th century, a renewed interest in classical economics gave rise to the
neo-Ricardian school and its offshoots.
Classical International Trade Economics
Adam Smith
Adam Smith (baptized 1723 – 17 July 1790) was a Scottish economist and philosopher who was a pioneer in the thinking of political economy and key figure during the Scottish Enlightenment. Seen by some as "The Father of Economics"——— ...
refuted
Mercantilist thought with his most influential publication: ''
An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations
''An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations'', generally referred to by its shortened title ''The Wealth of Nations'', is the ''Masterpiece, magnum opus'' of the Scottish people, Scottish economist and moral philosopher Ada ...
''.
He argued against mercantilism, and instead favored free trade and free markets, while believing that this would favor the countries who participate in
free trade. He elucidated that mercantilist policies would benefit domestic producers but not the country because it prevents consumers buying products at competitive prices, therefore directing cashflow ineffectively. Smith believed that deviating from free trade costs society in a similar manner as to how monopolies negatively affect competition in a market.
During the classical era and after Adam Smith,
David Ricardo became a prominent economist with thoughts on international trade. Ricardo’s most famous economic theory was the theory of
comparative advantage as the foundation of the international division of labor. He argued that international trade, in any case, would increase the
standard of living
Standard of living is the level of income, comforts and services available, generally applied to a society or location, rather than to an individual. Standard of living is relevant because it is considered to contribute to an individual's quality ...
.
His main idea on international trade was that while it does add to real output produced in a country, the main benefits are derived from the encouragement of specialization and the
division of labor
The division of labour is the separation of the tasks in any economic system or organisation so that participants may specialise (specialisation). Individuals, organizations, and nations are endowed with, or acquire specialised capabilities, and ...
on an international scale, leading to a more effective use of resources in all countries involved. One of Ricardo’s greatest assumptions and observations was that the
factors of production are immobile between countries while
finished goods
Finished goods are goods that have completed the manufacturing process but have not yet been sold or distributed to the end user.
Manufacturing
Manufacturing has three classes of inventory:
# Raw material
# Work in process
# Finished goods
A ...
are perfectly mobile, this assumption was critical to depict the advantages of international trade and specialization. His theory on international trade was weakened by how the
labor theory of value clashes with the theory of comparative advantage. Ultimately both theories collide with a question on how the price is relatively determined and Ricardo simply stated that it does not hold in
international trade theory
International trade theory is a sub-field of economics which analyzes the patterns of international trade, its origins, and its welfare implications. International trade policy has been highly controversial since the 18th century. Internationa ...
.
John Stuart Mill
John Stuart Mill (20 May 1806 – 7 May 1873) was an English philosopher, political economist, Member of Parliament (MP) and civil servant. One of the most influential thinkers in the history of classical liberalism, he contributed widely to ...
would later come and solve this dilemma and further build upon Ricardo’s theory of comparative advantage. John Stuart Mill’s contribution to Ricardo’s theory of comparative advantage came about when he introduced
demand to the equation. Mill introduced demand and was the first to promote the idea that demand and supply are functions of price, and the
market equilibrium is where price is adjusted to where there is equilibrium between supply and demand.
Overall, prior to Adam Smith and the classical economic wave, the main view of international trade was viewed negatively and not in favor of the countries who would participate in international trade with the economic policies of mercantilism. However, once Adam Smith, David Ricardo, and John Stuart Mill arrived with the classical wave of economics, international trade came to be viewed favorably and ultimately beneficial for all parties involved.
Classical theories of growth and development
Analyzing the growth in the wealth of nations and advocating policies to promote such growth was a major focus of most classical economists. However,
John Stuart Mill
John Stuart Mill (20 May 1806 – 7 May 1873) was an English philosopher, political economist, Member of Parliament (MP) and civil servant. One of the most influential thinkers in the history of classical liberalism, he contributed widely to ...
believed that a future stationary state of a constant population size and a constant stock of capital was both inevitable, necessary and desirable for mankind to achieve. This is now known as a
steady-state economy
A steady-state economy is an economy made up of a constant stock of physical wealth (capital) and a constant population size. In effect, such an economy does not grow in the course of time. The term usually refers to the national economy o ...
.
John Hicks &
Samuel Hollander
Samuel Hollander, (born April 6, 1937) is a British/Canadian/Israeli economist.
Born in London, he received a B.Sc. in economics from the London School of Economics in 1959. In 1961 he received an AM and a Ph.D. in 1963 from Princeton Universit ...
,
Nicholas Kaldor,
Luigi L. Pasinetti, and
Paul A. Samuelson[Samuelson, Paul A. (1978) "The Canonical Classical Model of Political Economy", ''Journal of Economic Literature'', V. 16: pp. 1415–34] have presented formal models as part of their respective interpretations of classical political economy.
Value theory
Classical economists developed a
theory of value, or price, to investigate economic dynamics. In political economics, value usually refers to the value of exchange, which is separate from the price.
William Petty introduced a fundamental distinction between
market price and
natural price to facilitate the portrayal of regularities in prices. Market prices are jostled by many transient influences that are difficult to theorize about at any abstract level. Natural prices, according to Petty, Smith, and Ricardo, for example, capture systematic and persistent forces operating at a point in time. Market prices always tend toward natural prices in a process that Smith described as somewhat similar to gravitational attraction.
The theory of what determined natural prices varied within the Classical school. Petty tried to develop a par between land and labour and had what might be called a land-and-labour theory of value. Smith confined the
labour theory of value to a mythical pre-capitalist past. Others may interpret Smith to have believed in value as derived from labour.
He stated that natural prices were the sum of natural rates of wages, profits (including interest on capital and wages of superintendence) and rent. Ricardo also had what might be described as a
cost of production theory of value
In economics, the cost-of-production theory of value is the theory that the price of an object or condition is determined by the sum of the cost of the resources that went into making it. The cost can comprise any of the factors of production (incl ...
. He criticized Smith for describing rent as price-determining, instead of price-determined, and saw the
labour theory of value as a good approximation.
Some historians of economic thought, in particular,
Sraffian economists,
[ Krishna Bharadwaj (1989) "Themes in Value and Distribution: Classical Theory Reppraised", Unwin-Hyman][Pierangelo Garegnani (1987), "Surplus Approach to Value and Distribution" in "The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics"] see the classical theory of prices as determined from three givens:
# The level of outputs at the level of Smith's "effectual demand",
# technology, and
# wages.
From these givens, one can rigorously derive a theory of value. But neither Ricardo nor Marx, the most rigorous investigators of the theory of value during the Classical period, developed this theory fully. Those who reconstruct the theory of value in this manner see the determinants of natural prices as being explained by the Classical economists from within the theory of economics, albeit at a lower level of abstraction. For example, the theory of wages was closely connected to the theory of population. The Classical economists took the theory of the determinants of the level and growth of population as part of Political Economy. Since then, the theory of population has been seen as part of
Demography. In contrast to the Classical theory, the following determinants of the neoclassical theory value are seen as exogenous to
neoclassical economics:
# tastes
# technology, and
# endowments.
Classical economics tended to stress the benefits of
trade. Its theory of value was largely displaced by
marginalist schools of thought which sees "
use value" as deriving from the
marginal utility
In economics, utility is the satisfaction or benefit derived by consuming a product. The marginal utility of a Goods (economics), good or Service (economics), service describes how much pleasure or satisfaction is gained by consumers as a result o ...
that consumers finds in a good, and "
exchange value
In political economy and especially Marxian economics, exchange value (German: ''Tauschwert'') refers to one of the four major attributes of a commodity, i.e., an item or service produced for, and sold on the market, the other three attributes be ...
" (i.e. natural price) as determined by the marginal
opportunity- or disutility-cost of the inputs that make up the product. Ironically, considering the attachment of many classical economists to the free market, the largest school of economic thought that still adheres to classical form is the
Marxian school.
Monetary theory
British classical economists in the 19th century had a well-developed controversy between the
Banking and the
Currency School. This parallels recent debates between proponents of the theory of
endogeneous money, such as
Nicholas Kaldor, and
monetarists, such as
Milton Friedman. Monetarists and members of the currency school argued that banks can and should control the supply of money. According to their theories, inflation is caused by banks issuing an excessive supply of money. According to proponents of the theory of
endogenous money, the supply of money automatically adjusts to the demand, and banks can only control the
terms and conditions
A contractual term is "any provision forming part of a contract". Each term gives rise to a contractual obligation, the breach of which may give rise to litigation. Not all terms are stated expressly and some terms carry less legal gravity as ...
(e.g., the rate of interest) on which loans are made.
Debates on the definition
The
theory of value is currently a contested subject. One issue is whether classical economics is a forerunner of
neoclassical economics or a school of thought that had a distinct theory of value, distribution, and growth.
The period 1830–75 is a timeframe of significant debate.
Karl Marx originally coined the term "classical economics" to refer to
Ricardian economics – the economics of David Ricardo and
James Mill and their ''predecessors'' – but usage was subsequently extended to include the ''followers'' of Ricardo.
['' The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money,'' John Maynard Keynes, Chapter 1]
Footnote 1
/ref>
Sraffians, who emphasize the discontinuity thesis
Discontinuity may refer to:
*Discontinuity (casting), an interruption in the normal physical structure or configuration of an article
* Discontinuity (geotechnical engineering), a plane or surface marking a change in physical or chemical propertie ...
,
see classical economics as extending from Petty's work in the 17th century to the break-up of the Ricardian system around 1830. The period between 1830 and the 1870s would then be dominated by "vulgar political economy", as Karl Marx characterized it. Sraffians argue that: the wages fund theory; Senior's abstinence theory of interest The abstinence theory of interest asserts that the money used for lending purposes is the money not used for consumption – which means, earning interest by abstaining from spending makes the funds possible and available for borrowers. , which puts the return to capital on the same level as returns to land and labour; the explanation of equilibrium prices by well-behaved supply and demand functions; and Say's law, are not necessary or essential elements of the classical theory of value and distribution. Perhaps Schumpeter's view that John Stuart Mill put forth a half-way house between classical and neoclassical economics is consistent with this view.
Georgists and other modern classical economists and historians such as Michael Hudson argue that a major division between classical and neo-classical economics is the treatment or recognition of Economic rent. Most modern economists no longer recognize land/location as a factor of production, often claiming that rent is non-existent. Georgists and others argue that economic rent remains roughly a third of economic output.
Sraffians generally see Marx as having rediscovered and restated the logic of classical economics, albeit for his own purposes. Others, such as Schumpeter, think of Marx as a follower of Ricardo. Even Samuel Hollander
Samuel Hollander, (born April 6, 1937) is a British/Canadian/Israeli economist.
Born in London, he received a B.Sc. in economics from the London School of Economics in 1959. In 1961 he received an AM and a Ph.D. in 1963 from Princeton Universit ...
[Samuel Hollander (2000), "Sraffa and the Interpretation of Ricardo: The Marxian Dimension", "History of Political Economy", V. 32, N. 2: 187–232 (2000)] has recently explained that there is a textual basis in the classical economists for Marx's reading, although he does argue that it is an extremely narrow set of texts.
Another position is that neoclassical economics is essentially continuous with classical economics. To scholars promoting this view, there is no hard and fast line between classical and neoclassical economics. There may be shifts of emphasis, such as between the long run and the short run and between supply and demand
In microeconomics, supply and demand is an economic model of price determination in a Market (economics), market. It postulates that, Ceteris paribus, holding all else equal, in a perfect competition, competitive market, the unit price for a ...
, but the neoclassical concepts are to be found confused or in embryo in classical economics. To these economists, there is only one theory of value and distribution. Alfred Marshall
Alfred Marshall (26 July 1842 – 13 July 1924) was an English economist, and was one of the most influential economists of his time. His book '' Principles of Economics'' (1890) was the dominant economic textbook in England for many years. I ...
is a well-known promoter of this view. Samuel Hollander
Samuel Hollander, (born April 6, 1937) is a British/Canadian/Israeli economist.
Born in London, he received a B.Sc. in economics from the London School of Economics in 1959. In 1961 he received an AM and a Ph.D. in 1963 from Princeton Universit ...
is probably its best current proponent.
Still another position sees two threads simultaneously being developed in classical economics. In this view, neoclassical economics is a development of certain exoteric (popular) views in Adam Smith. Ricardo was a sport, developing certain esoteric (known by only the select) views in Adam Smith. This view can be found in W. Stanley Jevons, who referred to Ricardo as something like "that able, but wrong-headed man" who put economics on the "wrong track". One can also find this view in Maurice Dobb's ''Theories of Value and Distribution Since Adam Smith: Ideology and Economic Theory'' (1973), as well as in Karl Marx's ''Theories of Surplus Value''.
The above does not exhaust the possibilities. John Maynard Keynes thought of classical economics as starting with Ricardo and being ended by the publication of his own ''General Theory of Employment Interest and Money''. The defining criterion of classical economics, on this view, is Say's law which is disputed by Keynesian economics. Keynes was aware, though, that his usage of the term 'classical' was non-standard.
One difficulty in these debates is that the participants are frequently arguing about whether there is a non-neoclassical theory that should be reconstructed and applied today to describe capitalist economies. Some, such as Terry Peach,[Terry Peach (1993), "Interpreting Ricardo", Cambridge University Press] see classical economics as of antiquarian interest.
See also
* Classical general equilibrium model
* Classical liberalism
Classical liberalism is a political tradition and a branch of liberalism that advocates free market and laissez-faire economics; civil liberties under the rule of law with especial emphasis on individual autonomy, limited government, e ...
* Constitutional economics
* Neoclassical economics
* Perspectives on capitalism
Throughout modern history, a variety of perspectives on capitalism have evolved based on different School of thought, schools of thought.
Overview
Adam Smith was one of the first influential writers on the topic with his book ''The Wealth of Na ...
* Political economy
References
Citations
Sources
* Mark Blaug (1987). "classical economics," '' The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics'', v. 1, pp. 414–45.
* _____ (2008). "British classical economics," '' The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics'', 2nd Edition
Abstract.
* Samuel Hollander
Samuel Hollander, (born April 6, 1937) is a British/Canadian/Israeli economist.
Born in London, he received a B.Sc. in economics from the London School of Economics in 1959. In 1961 he received an AM and a Ph.D. in 1963 from Princeton Universit ...
(1987). ''Classical Economics''. Oxford: Blackwell.
* Ernesto Screpanti
Ernesto Screpanti (born 1948, in Rome) is a professor of Political Economy at the University of Siena. He worked on the “rethinking Marxism” research programme, in the attempt to update Marxist analysis by bringing it in line with the reality o ...
and Stefano Zamagni (2005). ''An Outline of the History of Economic Thought''. Oxford University Press.
Further reading
*
*
External links