Rent controlled
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

Rent regulation is a system of laws, administered by a court or a public authority, which aims to ensure the affordability of housing and Tenancy, tenancies on the rental market for dwellings. Generally, a system of rent regulation involves: *Price controls, limits on the rent that a landlord may charge, typically called rent control or rent stabilization *Eviction controls: codified standards by which a landlord may terminate a tenancy *Obligations on the landlord or tenant regarding adequate maintenance of the property *A system of oversight and enforcement by an independent regulator and ombudsman The loose term "rent control" covers a spectrum of regulation which can vary from setting the absolute amount of rent that can be charged, with no allowed increases, to placing different limits on the amount that rent can increase; these restrictions may continue between tenancies, or may be applied only within the duration of a tenancy. As of 2016, at least 14 of the 36 OECD countries have some form of rent control in effect, including four states in the United States. Rent regulation is one of several classes of policies proposed to improve housing affordability, alongside Subsidized housing, subsidies (including Housing voucher, vouchers and tax credits) and policies aimed at expanding the housing supply. There is consensus among economists that rent control reduces the quality and quantity of rental housing units.


Forms of rent regulation

The loose term "rent control" can apply to several types of Price controls, price control: * "strict price ceilings", also known as ''rent freeze'' systems, or ''absolute'' or ''first generation'' rent controls, in which no increases in rent are allowed at all (rent is typically frozen at the rate existing when the law was enacted) * "vacancy control", also known as ''strict'' or ''strong'' rent control, in which the rental price can rise, but continues to be regulated in between tenancies (a new Leasehold estate, tenant pays almost the same rent as the previous tenant) and * "vacancy decontrol", also known as ''tenancy'' or ''second-generation'' rent control, which limits price increases during a tenancy, but allows rents to rise to market rate between tenancies (new tenants pay market rate rent, but increases are limited as long as they remain).


Economics


Theory

Rent price controls remain the most controversial element of a system of rent regulation. Historically, economists such as Adam Smith and David Ricardo viewed landlords as producing very little that was valuable, and so regarded "rents" as an exploitative concept. Economists note that the land value tax is a way to capture this unearned value. Modern rent controls (sometimes called rent leveling or rent stabilization) are intended to protect tenants in privately owned residential properties from excessive rent increases by mandating gradual rent increases, while at the same time ensuring that landlords receive a return on their investment that is deemed fair by the controlling authority. A number of Neoclassical economics, neo-classical and Keynesian economics, Keynesian economists say that some forms of rent control regulations create shortages and exacerbate scarcity in the housing market by discouraging private investment in the rental market. In addition, there would be a dead weight loss and inefficiency since some of the loss due to price ceilings is never gained again. This analysis targeted nominal rent freezes, and the studies conducted were mainly focused on rental prices in Manhattan, or elsewhere in the United States.


California studies

In 1994, San Francisco voters passed a ballot initiative which expanded the city's existing rent control laws to include small multi-unit apartments with four or fewer units, built prior to 1980 (about 30% of the city's rental housing stock at the time). A 2019 study found that San Francisco's rent control laws reduced tenant displacement from rent controlled units in the short-term, but resulted in landlords removing 30% of the rent controlled units from the rental market (by conversion to Condominium, condos or Concurrent estate#Tenancy in common, TICs) which led to a 15% citywide decrease in total rental units, and a 7% increase in citywide rents.


Economists' views

In a 1992 Stratified sampling, stratified, random survey of 464 US economists, economics graduate school, graduate students, and members of the American Economic Association, 93% "generally agreed" or "agreed with wikt:proviso, provisos" that "A ceiling on rents reduces the quantity and quality of housing available." A 2009 review of the economic literature by Blair Jenkins through EconLit covering theoretical and empirical research on multiple aspects of the issue, including housing availability, maintenance and housing quality, rental rates, political and administrative costs, and redistribution, for both first generation and second generation rent control systems, found that "the economics profession has reached a rare consensus: Rent control creates many more problems than it solves". In a 2012 poll of 41 economists by the Initiative on Global Markets (IGM) Economic Experts Panel, which queried opinions on the statement "Local ordinances that limit rent increases for some rental housing units, such as in New York and San Francisco, have had a positive impact over the past three decades on the amount and quality of broadly affordable rental housing in cities that have used them," 13 members said they strongly disagreed, 20 disagreed, 1 agreed, and 7 either did not answer, were undecided, or had no opinion. In a 2013 analysis of the body of economic research on rent control by Peter Tatian at the Urban Institute, he stated that "The conclusion seems to be that rent stabilization doesn't do a good job of protecting its intended beneficiaries—poor or vulnerable renters—because the targeting of the benefits is very haphazard.", and concluded that: "Given the current research, there seems to be little one can say in favor of rent control." Many economists suggest housing subsidies as a way to make housing more affordable to renters without distorting the housing market as much as rent control, but expanding the existing subsidy programs would require sharp increases in government spending. Paul Krugman writes that rent control inhibits construction of new housing, creates bitter tenant–landlord relations, and in markets with not all apartments under rent control, causes an increase in rents for uncontrolled units. Thomas Sowell writes that rent control reduces the supply of housing, and has stated that rent control increases urban blight. The Swedish economist Assar Lindbeck, a housing expert, said that "rent control appears to be the most efficient technique presently known to destroy a city – except for bombing".


History


Early modern Europe

Rent control was used in Rome as early as 1470 to protect Jewish residents from price gouging. Since Jews in the Papal States were forbidden to own property, they were dependent on Christians, Christian landlords, who charged them high rents. In 1562, Pope Pius IV granted Jews the right to own property worth up to 1500 Roman scudi and enacted rent stabilization. In 1586, Pope Sixtus V issued a bull ordering landlords to rent out houses to Jewish tenants at reasonable rates.


Politics


California

A survey conducted in 2018 by the ''Los Angeles Times'' and the University of Southern California found that 28% of eligible California voters believed that the lack of rent control was the main contributing factor to California's Housing affordability in California, housing affordability crisis. 24% of respondents believed that the most significant cause of the Homelessness in the United States, housing crisis was insufficient funding of low-income housing; only 13% believed it was insufficient new housing. In 2018, a statewide initiative (2018 California Proposition 10, Proposition 10) attempted to repeal the Costa-Hawkins Rental Housing Act, which, if passed, would have allowed cities and municipalities to enact "vacancy control" systems, allowed rent control to be applied to buildings newer than 1995, and would have allowed rent control on single-family homes. (All currently prohibited by Costa-Hawkins.) The proposition failed, 59% to 41%. Another attempt to allow more rent control, 2020 California Proposition 21, failed by an almost identical margin.


US Pacific Northwest

US states in the pacific northwest region have a history of rent control practices, though in recent decades housing market conditions as well as deregulatory practices have contributed significantly to sharp increases in price. For example Oregonian home renters have faced a consistent rent increase year after year and from the median rental prices of rent the contemporary period, there is likely no foreseeable end. This circumstance is not just an Oregon problem but rather one that is endemic to the pacific northwest as well as nationwide. These complications will likely negatively impact families and single-home renters. While the problem persists, state governments have created subsidized programs that can help a limited number of rental households in maintaining their rentals.


Rent regulation by country


Australia

Rental regulations are largely administered by the state and territory governments. Rent control and freezes were features of the First and Second World War, the Great Depression in Australia, Great Depression and the early stages of the COVID-19 pandemic. However the Australian Capital Territory is currently the only jurisdiction with regulation specifying maximum rent increases. Rents can only be increased once a year by a maximum of 110% of the consumer price index for the cost of rent in the ACT. Other jurisdictions allow for rent increases every six to twelve months with variable notice periods.


Canada

In Canada, there are rent regulation laws in each province. For example, in Ontario the Residential Tenancies Act 2006 requires that prices for rented properties do not rise more than 2.5 percent each year, or a lower figure fixed by a government minister.


China

China announced in August 2021 new nationwide rent regulations that cap maximum yearly rent increases to 5% in all urban areas, which comprise over 2/3 of the population and include most of the ~250 million renters in the country.


France

Rent regulations are determined in France based on the Rent Reference Index, which serves as the basis for what landlords can increase yearly rents by. In July 2022, France introduced a new cap on yearly rent increase of a maximum of 3.5% for one year.


Germany

German rent regulation is found in the "Civil Code" (the ''Bürgerliches Gesetzbuch'') in § 535 to § 580a. As common in German law, regulations are structured into an abstract, more general part that applies to all contracts of a certain type, followed by a more specific section for individual fields of application of this type of contract. Specific regulations for rental contracts governing apartments range from §§ 549 - 577a BGB. The German law differentiates between the rental price at the starting point of the contract and rent increases throughout the duration of the contract. Generally, the rental price at the starting point of the contract is determined by the contractual agreement between the parties. Only in designated regions with a strained housing market, the rental price at the beginning of the rental agreement are capped by law. Increases in the rental prices throughout the duration of a rental contract are required to follow a "rent level" (''Mietspiegel''), which is a database of local reference rent prices. This collects all rent prices of new rental contracts of the past four years, and landlords may only increase prices on their property in line with rents in the same locality. Usury Rents are prohibited altogether, so that any price rises above 20 per cent over three years are unlawful. Tenants may be evicted against their will through a court procedure for a good reason, and in the normal case only with a minimum of three months' notice. Tenants receive unlimited duration of their rental agreement unless the duration is explicitly halted. In practice, landlords have little incentive to change tenants as rental price increases beyond inflation are constrained. During the period of the tenancy, a person's tenancy may only be terminated for very good reasons. A system of rights for the rental property to be maintained by the landlord is designed to ensure quality of housing. Many states, such as Berlin, have a constitutional right to adequate housing, and require buildings to make dwelling spaces of a certain size and ceiling height. In 2020, Berlin implemented a rent freeze, which was unprecedented in the German housing market. It benefitted sitting renters, but it substantially reduced the supply of new housing, harming those looking for a dwelling. The rent freeze was repealed in 2021.


Netherlands

Yearly rent increases in the Netherlands are capped at a maximum of inflation + 1%, calculated as 3.3% in 2022.


Spain

The Catalonia region of Spain passed a rent-regulation law in September 2020.


United Kingdom

Rent regulation covered the whole of the UK private sector rental market from 1915 to 1980. However, from the Housing Act 1980, it became the Conservative Party (UK), Conservative Party's policy to deregulate and dismantle rent regulation. Regulation for all new tenancies was abolished by the Housing Act 1988, leaving the basic regulatory framework was "freedom of contract" by the landlord to set any price. Rent regulations survive among a small number of council houses, and often the rates set by local authorities mirror escalating prices in the non-regulated private market.


United States

Rent regulation in the United States is an issue for each state. In 1921, the US supreme court, US Supreme Court case of ''Block v. Hirsh'' held by a majority that regulation of rents in the District of Columbia as a temporary emergency measure was constitutional, but shortly afterwards in 1924 in ''Chastleton Corp v. Sinclair'' the same law was unanimously struck down by the Supreme Court. After the 1930s New Deal, the Supreme Court ceased to interfere with social and economic legislation, and a number of states adopted rules. In the 1986 case of ''Fisher v. City of Berkeley'', the US Supreme court held that there was no incompatibility between rent control and the Sherman Act. As of 2018, four states (California, New York (state), New York, New Jersey, and Maryland) and the District of Columbia have localities in which some form of residential rent control is in effect (for normal structures, excluding mobile homes). Thirty-seven states either prohibit or preempt rent control, while nine states allow their cities to enact rent control, but have no cities that have implemented it. For the localities with rent control, it often covers a large percentage of that city's stock of rental units: For example, in some of the largest markets: in New York City in 2011, 45% of rental units were either "rent stabilized" or "rent controlled", (these are different legal classifications in NYC) in the District of Columbia in 2014, just over 50% of rental units were rent controlled, in San Francisco, as of 2014, about 75% of all rental units were rent controlled, and in Los Angeles in 2014, 80% of ''multifamily'' units were rent controlled. In 2019 California passed the Tenant Protection Act which limits yearly rent increases to 5% + % change in CPI, up to a maximum of 10%. In 2019 Oregon's legislature passed a bill which made the state the first in the nation to adopt a state-wide rent control policy. This new law limits annual rent increases to inflation plus 7 percent, includes vacancy decontrol (market rate between tenancies), exempts new construction for 15 years, and keeps the current state ban on local rent control policies (state level preemption) intact. In November 2021, voters in Saint Paul, Minnesota passed a rent control ballot initiative which capped annual rent increases at 3 percent, included vacancy control, and did not exempt new construction, nor allow inflation to be added to the allowable rate increase. This resulted in an 80% reduction in requests for new multifamily housing permits, while in neighboring Minneapolis, where voters authorized the city council to craft a rent control ordinance, yet to be enacted—which may exempt new construction from the rent control caps—permits were up 68%.


See also

* Affordable housing * Housing inequality * NIMBY * Public housing * Subsidized housing


References


Further reading

*R Arnott, 'Time for Revisionism on Rent Control?' (1995
9(1) Journal of Economic Perspectives 99
*A Anas, 'Rent Control with Matching Economies: A Model of European Housing Market Regulation' (1997) 15(1) Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 111–37 *T Ellingsen and P Englund, 'Rent regulation: An introduction' (2003) 10 Swedish Economic Policy Review 3 *H Lind, 'Rent Regulation: A Conceptual and Comparative Analysis' (2001
1(1) International Journal of Housing Policy 41
*C Rapkin, ''The Private Rental Housing Market in New York City'' (1966) *G Sternlieb, ''The Urban Housing Dilemma'' (1972) *P Weitzman, 'Economics and Rent Regulation: A Call for a New Perspective' (1984–1985) 13 NYU Review of Legal and Social Change 975–988 *M Haffner, M Elsinga and J Hoekstra, 'Rent Regulation: The Balance between Private Landlords and Tenants in Six European Countries' (2008) 8(2) International Journal of Housing Policy 217


External links


Rent Control Around the World: Pros and Cons – Including summaries of rent control laws in many countries
{{Real estate Rent regulation, Affordable housing de:Mietvertrag (Deutschland) fr:Contrôle des loyers