Léon Walras
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

Marie-Esprit-Léon Walras (; 16 December 1834 – 5 January 1910) was a French mathematical economist and
Georgist Georgism, also called in modern times Geoism, and known historically as the single tax movement, is an economic ideology holding that, although people should own the value they produce themselves, the economic rent derived from Land (economics), ...
. He formulated the marginal theory of value (independently of
William Stanley Jevons William Stanley Jevons (; 1 September 183513 August 1882) was an English economist and logician. Irving Fisher described Jevons's book ''A General Mathematical Theory of Political Economy'' (1862) as the start of the mathematical method in ec ...
and Carl Menger) and pioneered the development of general equilibrium theory. Walras is best known for his book ''Éléments d'économie politique pure'', a work that has contributed greatly to the mathematization of economics through the concept of general equilibrium. The definition of the role of the entrepreneur found in it was also taken up and amplified by Joseph Schumpeter. For Walras, exchanges only take place after a Walrasian '' tâtonnement'' (French for "trial and error"), guided by the auctioneer, has made it possible to reach market equilibrium. It was the general equilibrium obtained from a single hypothesis, rarity, that led Joseph Schumpeter to consider him "the greatest of all economists". The notion of general equilibrium was very quickly adopted by major economists such as Vilfredo Pareto,
Knut Wicksell Johan Gustaf Knut Wicksell (December 20, 1851 – May 3, 1926) was a leading Swedish economist of the Stockholm school. His economic contributions would influence both the Keynesian and Austrian schools of economic thought. He was married to t ...
and Gustav Cassel.
John Hicks Sir John Richards Hicks (8 April 1904 – 20 May 1989) was a British economist. He is considered one of the most important and influential economists of the twentieth century. The most familiar of his many contributions in the field of economic ...
and Paul Samuelson used the Walrasian contribution in the elaboration of the neoclassical synthesis. For their part, Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu, from the perspective of a logician and a mathematician, determined the conditions necessary for equilibrium.


Biography

Walras was the son of a French school administrator Auguste Walras. His father was not a professional economist, yet his economic thinking had a profound effect on his son. He found the value of goods by setting their scarcity relative to human wants. Walras enrolled in the
École des Mines de Paris Mines Paris - PSL, officially École nationale supérieure des mines de Paris (until May 2022 Mines ParisTech, also known as École des mines de Paris, ENSMP, Mines de Paris, les Mines, or Paris School of Mines), is a French grande école and a ...
, but grew tired of engineering. He worked as a bank manager, journalist, romantic novelist and railway clerk before turning to economics.'' Economyths'' (2010) by David Orrell, p. 54 Walras received an appointment as the professor of political economy at the University of Lausanne. Walras also inherited his father's interest in
social reform A reform movement or reformism is a type of social movement that aims to bring a social or also a political system closer to the community's ideal. A reform movement is distinguished from more radical social movements such as revolutionary mov ...
. Much like the Fabians, Walras called for the nationalization of land, believing that land's productivity would always increase and that rents from that land would be sufficient to support the nation without taxes. He also asserts that all other taxes (i.e. on goods, labor, capital) eventually realize effects exactly identical to a consumption tax, so they can hurt the economy (unlike a land tax). Another of Walras's influences was Augustin Cournot, a former schoolmate of his father. Through Cournot, Walras came under the influence of
rationalism In philosophy, rationalism is the epistemological view that "regards reason as the chief source and test of knowledge" or "any view appealing to reason as a source of knowledge or justification".Lacey, A.R. (1996), ''A Dictionary of Philosophy' ...
and was introduced to the use of mathematics in economics. As Professor of
Political Economy Political economy is the study of how economic systems (e.g. markets and national economies) and political systems (e.g. law, institutions, government) are linked. Widely studied phenomena within the discipline are systems such as labour ...
at the
University of Lausanne The University of Lausanne (UNIL; french: links=no, Université de Lausanne) in Lausanne, Switzerland was founded in 1537 as a school of Protestant theology, before being made a university in 1890. The university is the second oldest in Switzer ...
, Walras is credited with founding the Lausanne school of economics, along with his successor Vilfredo Pareto. Because most of Walras's publications were only available in French, many economists were unfamiliar with his work. This changed in 1954 with the publication of William Jaffé's English translation of Walras's ''Éléments d'économie politique pure''. Walras's work was also too mathematically complex for many contemporary readers of his time. On the other hand, it has a great insight into the market process under idealized conditions so it has been far more read in the modern era. Although Walras came to be regarded as one of the three leaders of the marginalist revolution, he was not familiar with the two other leading figures of marginalism,
William Stanley Jevons William Stanley Jevons (; 1 September 183513 August 1882) was an English economist and logician. Irving Fisher described Jevons's book ''A General Mathematical Theory of Political Economy'' (1862) as the start of the mathematical method in ec ...
and Carl Menger, and developed his theories independently. ''Elements'' has Walras disagreeing with Jevons on the applicability, while the findings adopted by Carl Menger, he says, are completely in alignment with the ideas present in the book (even though expressed non-mathematically).


Life and career


General equilibrium theory

In 1874 and 1877 Walras published ''Éléments d'économie politique pure'' (1899, 4th ed.; 1926, éd. définitive), in English, ''Elements of Pure Economics'' (1954), trans. William Jaffé. That work that led him to be considered the father of the general equilibrium theory. The problem that Walras set out to solve was one presented by A. A. Cournot, that even though it could be demonstrated that prices would equate
supply and demand In microeconomics, supply and demand is an economic model of price determination in a Market (economics), market. It postulates that, Ceteris paribus, holding all else equal, in a perfect competition, competitive market, the unit price for a ...
to clear individual markets, it was unclear that an equilibrium existed for all markets simultaneously.
Walras's law Walras's law is a principle in general equilibrium theory asserting that budget constraints imply that the ''values'' of excess demand (or, conversely, excess market supplies) must sum to zero regardless of whether the prices are general equilibri ...
implies that the sum of the values of excess demands across all markets must equal zero, whether or not the economy is in a general equilibrium. This implies that if positive excess demand exists in one market, negative excess demand must exist in some other market. Thus, if all markets but one are in equilibrium, then that last market must also be in equilibrium. While teaching at the Lausanne Academy, Walras began constructing a mathematical model that assumes a "regime of perfectly free competition", in which productive factors, products, and prices automatically adjust in equilibrium. Walras began with the theory of exchange in 1873 and then he proceeded to map out his theories of production, capitalization and money in his first edition. His theory of exchange began with an expansion of Cournot's demand curve to include more than two commodities, also realizing the value of the quantity sold must equal the quantity purchased thus the ratio of prices must be equal to the inverse ratio of quantities. Walras then drew a supply curve from the demand curve and set equilibrium prices at the intersection. His model could now determine prices of commodities but only the relative price. In order to deduce the absolute price, Walras could choose one price to serve as a unit of account, coined by Walras as the numeraire and state all other prices in units of this commodity. The term numeraire, meaning unit of account, has become part of the international vocabulary of economics and for many economists, the only French word they know. Using this numeraire he determined that marginal utility, or rarete, divided by the price must be equal for all commodities. Walras felt that because the value of what an individual consumer consumes is equal to the value of that individual's stock of goods, that the aggregate, the value of total sales must equal the value of total purchase, must hold true. This became known as Walras' Law which held that equilibrium equations can be derived from the others until only m-1 equations in the m-1 relative prices remain. Walras then expanded the theory to include production with the assumption of an existence of fixed coefficients in said production making possible a generalization that the marginal productivity of the factors of production varied with the amount of input, making factor substitution possible. Walras constructed his basic theory of general equilibrium by beginning with simple equations and then increasing the complexity in the next equations. He began with a two-person bartering system, then moved on to the derivation of downward-sloping consumer demands. Next he moved on to exchanges involving multiple parties, and finally ended with credit and money. Walras wrote down four sets of equations—one representing the quantity of goods demanded, one relating the prices of goods to their costs of production, one for the quantities of inputs supplied, and one showing the quantities of inputs demanded. There are four sets of variables to solve for, namely, the price of each good, the quantity of each good sold, the price of each factor of production, and the quantity of each of those factor bought by businesses. To simplify matters, Walras added one further equation to his model, requiring that all the money received must be spent, one way or the other. But there are now more equations than unknowns. From the theory of equations, one learns that a necessary but insufficient condition for the existence of a unique solution to a system of equations is that the number of equations must equal the number of variables. Walras tackled this problem by selecting an arbitrary good, G1, whose price is designated as the standard against which the prices of the other goods shall be compared. The system of equations can now be solved for the prices of all goods in terms of G1, though not for the absolute price levels.Pressman, Steven. ''Fifty Major Economists''. "Léon Walras (1834-1910)." 2nd ed., Routledge, 2006. The crucial step in the argument was
Walras's law Walras's law is a principle in general equilibrium theory asserting that budget constraints imply that the ''values'' of excess demand (or, conversely, excess market supplies) must sum to zero regardless of whether the prices are general equilibri ...
which states that any particular market must be in equilibrium, if all other markets in an economy are also in equilibrium. Walras's law hinges on the mathematical notion that excess market demands (or, inversely, excess market supplies) must sum to zero. This means that, in an economy with n markets, it is sufficient to solve n-1 simultaneous equations for market clearing. Taking one good as the numéraire in terms of which prices are specified, the economy has n-1 prices that can be determined by the equation, so an equilibrium should exist. Although Walras set out the framework for thinking about the existence of equilibrium clearly and precisely his attempt to demonstrate existence by counting the number of equations and variables was severely flawed: it is easy to see that not all pairs of equations in two variables have solutions. A more rigorous version of the argument was developed independently by Lionel McKenzie and the pair
Kenneth Arrow Kenneth Joseph Arrow (23 August 1921 – 21 February 2017) was an American economist, mathematician, writer, and political theorist. He was the joint winner of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences with John Hicks in 1972. In economi ...
and Gérard Debreu in the 1950s. A significant part of the general equilibrium theory as introduced by Walras has become known as the Walrasian auction which is a type of simultaneous auction where each agent calculates its demand for the good at every possible price and submits this to an auctioneer. The price is then set so that the total demand across all agents equals the total amount of the good. Thus, a Walrasian auction perfectly matches the supply and the demand. Walras suggests that equilibrium will be achieved through a process of ''tâtonnement'' (French for "trial and error"), a form of incremental hill climbing.


Economic value definition of utility

Léon Walras provides a definition of economic utility based on economic value as opposed to an ethical theory of value:
I state that things are useful as soon as they may serve whatever usage, as soon as they match whatever need and allow its fulfillment. Thus, there is here no point to deal with 'nuances' by way of which one classes, in the language of everyday conversation, utility beside what is pleasant and between the necessary and the superfluous. Necessary, useful, pleasant and superfluous, all of this is, for us, more or less useful. There is here as well no need to take into account the morality or immorality of the need that the useful things matches and permits to fulfill. Whether a substance is searched for by a doctor to heal an ill person, or by an assassin to poison his family, this is an important question from other points of view, albeit totally indifferent from ours. The substance is useful, for us, in both cases, and may well be more useful in the second case than in the first one.
In economic theories of value, the term "value" is unrelated to any notions of value used in ethics, they are homonyms.


Legacy

In 1941 George Stigler wrote about Walras: What caused the re-appraisal of Walras's consideration in the US, was the influx of German-speaking scientists – the German version of the ''Éléments'' was published in 1881. According to
Schumpeter Joseph Alois Schumpeter (; February 8, 1883 – January 8, 1950) was an Austrian-born political economist. He served briefly as Finance Minister of German-Austria in 1919. In 1932, he emigrated to the United States to become a professor at ...
:


Major works


''Éléments d'Économie Politique Pure''

The ''Éléments'' of 1874/1877 are the work by which Léon Walras is best known. The full title is * Éléments d'Économie Politique Pure, ou Théorie de la richesse sociale. The half title page uses only the title ('Éléments d'Économie Politique Pure') whereas inside the body (e.g. p. 1 and the contents page) the subtitle ('Théorie de la richesse sociale') is used as if it were the title.


Plan of work

The work was issued in two instalments (''fascicules'') in separate years. It was intended as the first of three parts of a systematic treatise as follows: * 1re partie:– Éléments d'Économie Politique Pure, ou Théorie de la richesse sociale. ** Section I. Objet et divisions de l'économie politique et sociale. ** Section II. Théorie mathématique de l'échange. ** Section III. Du numéraire et de la monnaie. ** Section IV. Théorie naturelle de la production et de la conommation de la richesse. ** Section V. Conditions et conséquences du progrès économique. ** Section VI. Effets naturels et nécessaires des divers modes d'organisation économique de la société. * 2e partie:– Éléments d'Économie Politique Appliquée, ou Théorie de la production agricole, industrielle et commerciale de la richesse. * 3e partie:– Éléments d'Économie Sociale, ou Théorie de la répartition de la richesse par la propriété et l'impôt. Works with titles echoing those proposed for Parts II and III were published in 1898 and 1896. They are included in the list of other works below.


Editions

* ''First'' (1874/1877). Most readily available. Described by Walker and van Daal as a 'brilliant expression of pure originality, containing many theoretical innovations' which 'needed alteration and development in a variety of important respects'. * ''Second'' (1889). Revised, corrected and enlarged. * ''Third'' (1896). A minor revision with new appendices. This is considered the best edition by Walker and van Daal. * ''Fourth'' (1900). Revised and extended. According to Walker and van Daal, 'these changes resulted in an incomplete, internally contradictory, and occasionally incoherent text'. * ''Fifth'' (1926). Posthumous; published by his daughter Aline. 'Édition définitive, revue et augmentée'. Follows the fourth.


Derived work

The 'Théorie Mathématique de la Richesse Sociale' included in the list of other works (below) is described by the National Library of Australia as 'a series of lectures and articles that together summarize the mathematical elements of the author's ''Élements'' '.Catalogue record at https://catalogue.nla.gov.au/Record/2018624.


English Translations

* William Jaffé (1954) of the ''fifth'' edition as ''Elements of Pure Economics''. * Donald A. Walker and Jan van Daal (2014) of the ''third'' edition as ''Elements of Theoretical Economics''. Walker and van Daal describe Jaffé's translation of the word ''crieur'' as 'a momentous error that has misled generations of readers'.


Online and facsimile editions

* Online: * Facsimile: cheap photographic reprints are produced by . Both of these are made from the ''first'' edition and are defective in respect of illustrations. The original figures were included as folding plates (presumably at the end of each ''fascicule''). The online edition contains only Figs. 3, 4, 10, and 12 whereas the facsimile contains only Figs. 5 and 6.


Other works

* ''Francis Saveur'', 1858. * "De la propriété intellectuelle", 1859, ''Journal des économistes''. * * "Paradoxes économiques I", 1860, ''Journal des économistes''. * "Théorie critique de l'impôt", 1861. * ''De l'impôt dans le Canton de Vaud'', 1861. * * "La bourse et le crédit", 1867, ''Paris Guide''. * * "Correspondance entre M. Jevons, professeur a Manchester, et M. Walras, professeur a Lausanne", 1874, ''Journal des économistes''. * * "Un nuovo ramo della matematica. Dell' applicazione delle matematiche all' economia politica", 1876, ''Giornale degli economisti''. * ''Théorie mathématique de la richesse sociale'', 1883. * "Notice autobiographique de Léon Walras", 1893. * ''Études d'économie sociale; Théorie de la répartition de la richesse sociale'', 1896. * ''Études d'économie politique appliquée; Théorie de la production de la richesse sociale'', 1898. * "Théorie du crédit", 1898, ''Revue d'économie politique''. * "Sur les équations de la circulation", 1899, ''Giornale degli economisti'' * "Cournot et l'Économique Mathématique", 1905, ''Gazette de Lausanne''. * "La Paix par la Justice Sociale et le Libre Échange", 1907, ''Questions Pratiques de Legislation Ouvrière''. * ''L'état et le chemin de fer'' (1875). * "Leone Walras, Autobiografia", 1908, ''Giornale degli Economist''i. * "Un initiateur en économie politique, A.A. Walras", 1908, ''La Revue du Mois''. * "Économique et méchanique", 1909, ''Bulletin de la Société Vaudoise de Sciences Naturelles'' * ''Correspondence of Léon Walras and related papers'' (ed. by William Jaffé, 3 vols.), 1965.


See also

*
Walras's law Walras's law is a principle in general equilibrium theory asserting that budget constraints imply that the ''values'' of excess demand (or, conversely, excess market supplies) must sum to zero regardless of whether the prices are general equilibri ...
* Walrasian auction *
General equilibrium In economics, general equilibrium theory attempts to explain the behavior of supply, demand, and prices in a whole economy with several or many interacting markets, by seeking to prove that the interaction of demand and supply will result in an o ...
* Cost the limit of price * Progressive theory of capital


Note


References


Further reading

* Jaffé, William, and Donald A. Walker (ed.) (1983). ''Essays on Walras''. Cambridge University Press. * Morishima, Michio (1977). ''Walras' economics : a pure theory of capital and money''. Cambridge University Press. * Medema S.G. & Samuels W.J. (2003). "The history of economic thought: a reader" Routledge, London and New York.


External links


Biography and major works
* {{DEFAULTSORT:Walras, Leon Mines ParisTech alumni 1834 births 1910 deaths People from Évreux General equilibrium theorists 19th-century French economists 20th-century French economists University of Lausanne faculty Georgist economists Neoclassical economists