HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

In economics, the marginal product of labor (MPL) is the change in
output Output may refer to: * The information produced by a computer, see Input/output * An output state of a system, see state (computer science) * Output (economics), the amount of goods and services produced ** Gross output in economics, the value o ...
that results from employing an added unit of
labor Labour or labor may refer to: * Childbirth, the delivery of a baby * Labour (human activity), or work ** Manual labour, physical work ** Wage labour, a socioeconomic relationship between a worker and an employer ** Organized labour and the la ...
. It is a feature of the
production function In economics, a production function gives the technological relation between quantities of physical inputs and quantities of output of goods. The production function is one of the key concepts of mainstream neoclassical theories, used to define ...
, and depends on the amounts of
physical capital Physical capital represents in economics one of the three primary factors of production. Physical capital is the apparatus used to produce a good and services. Physical capital represents the tangible man-made goods that help and support the produ ...
and labor already in use.


Definition

The
marginal product In economics and in particular neoclassical economics, the marginal product or marginal physical productivity of an input (factor of production) is the change in output resulting from employing one more unit of a particular input (for instance, th ...
of a
factor of production In economics, factors of production, resources, or inputs are what is used in the production process to produce output—that is, goods and services. The utilized amounts of the various inputs determine the quantity of output according to the rel ...
is generally defined as the change in output resulting from a unit or infinitesimal change in the quantity of that factor used, holding all other input usages in the production process constant. The marginal product of labor is then the change in output (''Y'') per unit change in labor (''L''). In discrete terms the marginal product of labor is: : \frac . In continuous terms, the ''MPL'' is the first
derivative In mathematics, the derivative of a function of a real variable measures the sensitivity to change of the function value (output value) with respect to a change in its argument (input value). Derivatives are a fundamental tool of calculus. ...
of the
production function In economics, a production function gives the technological relation between quantities of physical inputs and quantities of output of goods. The production function is one of the key concepts of mainstream neoclassical theories, used to define ...
: : \frac .Perloff, J., ''Microeconomics Theory and Applications with Calculus'', Pearson 2008. p. 173. Graphically, the ''MPL'' is the slope of the production function.


Examples

There is a factory which produces toys. When there are no workers in the factory, no toys are produced. When there is one worker in the factory, six toys are produced per hour. When there are two workers in the factory, eleven toys are produced per hour. There is a marginal product of labor of five when there are two workers in the factory compared to one. When the marginal product of labor is increasing, this is called increasing marginal returns. However, as the number of workers increases, the marginal product of labor may not increase indefinitely. When not scaled properly, the marginal product of labor may go down when the number of employees goes up, creating a situation known as diminishing marginal returns. When the marginal product of labor becomes negative, it is known as negative marginal returns.


Marginal costs

The marginal product of labor is directly related to
costs of production In production, research, retail, and accounting, a cost is the value of money that has been used up to produce something or deliver a service, and hence is not available for use anymore. In business, the cost may be one of acquisition, in which ...
.
Cost In production, research, retail, and accounting, a cost is the value of money that has been used up to produce something or deliver a service, and hence is not available for use anymore. In business, the cost may be one of acquisition, in whic ...
s are divided between fixed and
variable cost Variable costs are costs that change as the quantity of the good or service that a business produces changes.Garrison, Noreen, Brewer. Ch 2 - Managerial Accounting and Costs Concepts, pp 48 Variable costs are the sum of marginal costs over all un ...
s. Fixed costs are costs that relate to the fixed input, capital, or ''rK'', where ''r'' is the rental cost of capital and ''K'' is the quantity of capital. Variable costs (VC) are the costs of the variable input, labor, or ''wL'', where ''w'' is the wage rate and ''L'' is the amount of labor employed. Thus, VC = wL . Marginal cost (MC) is the change in total cost per unit change in output or ∆C/∆Q. In the short run, production can be varied only by changing the variable input. Thus only variable costs change as output increases: ∆C = ∆VC = ∆(wL). Marginal cost is ∆(Lw)/∆Q. Now, ∆L/∆Q is the reciprocal of the marginal product of labor (∆Q/∆L). Therefore, marginal cost is simply the wage rate w divided by the marginal product of labor : MC = \frac : = w : / (the change in quantity of labor to effect a one unit change in output) = 1/MP_L Therefore MC = w/MP_L Thus if the marginal product of labor is rising then marginal costs will be falling and if the marginal product of labor is falling marginal costs will be rising (assuming a constant wage rate).


Relation between MPL and APL

The average product of labor (APL) is the total product of labor divided by the number of units of labor employed, or ''Q/L''. The average product of labor is a common measure of labor productivity. The APL curve is shaped like an inverted “u”. At low production levels the APL tends to increase as additional labor is added. The primary reason for the increase is specialization and division of labor.Perloff, J., ''Microeconomics Theory and Applications with Calculus'', Pearson 2008, p. 176. At the point the APL reaches its maximum value APL equals the MPL. Beyond this point the APL falls. During the early stages of production MPL is greater than APL. When the MPL is above the APL the APL will increase. Eventually the ''MPL'' reaches it maximum value at the point of diminishing returns. Beyond this point MPL will decrease. However, at the point of diminishing returns the MPL is still above the APL and APL will continue to increase until MPL equals APL. When MPL is below APL, APL will decrease. Graphically, the ''APL'' curve can be derived from the total product curve by drawing secants from the origin that intersect (cut) the total product curve. The slope of the secant line equals the average product of labor, where the slope = dQ/dL. The slope of the curve at each intersection marks a point on the average product curve. The slope increases until the line reaches a point of tangency with the total product curve. This point marks the maximum average product of labor. It also marks the point where MPL (which is the slope of the total product curve) equals the APL (the slope of the secant). Beyond this point the slope of the secants become progressively smaller as ''APL'' declines. The MPL curve intersects the APL curve from above at the maximum point of the APL curve. Thereafter, the MPL curve is below the APL curve.


Diminishing marginal returns

The falling MPL is due to the law of diminishing marginal returns. The law states, "as units of one input are added (with all other inputs held constant) a point will be reached where the resulting additions to output will begin to decrease; that is marginal product will decline."Samuelson, W. and S. Marks, ''Managerial Economics'', 4th ed. Wiley 2003, p. 227. The law of diminishing marginal returns applies regardless of whether the production function exhibits increasing, decreasing ,or constant returns to scale. The key factor is that the variable input is being changed while all other factors of production are being held constant. Under such circumstances diminishing marginal returns are inevitable at some level of production.
Hal Varian Hal Ronald Varian (born March 18, 1947 in Wooster, Ohio) is Chief Economist at Google and holds the title of emeritus professor at the University of California, Berkeley where he was founding dean of the School of Information. Varian is an eco ...
, ''Microeconomic Analysis'', 3rd ed. Norton 1992.
Diminishing marginal returns differs from diminishing returns. Diminishing marginal returns means that the marginal product of the variable input is falling. Diminishing returns occur when the marginal product of the variable input is negative. That is when a unit increase in the variable input causes total product to fall. At the point that diminishing returns begin the MPL is zero.Perloff, J., ''Microeconomics Theory and Applications with Calculus'', Pearson 2008, p. 178.


MPL, MRPL and profit maximization

The general rule is that a firm maximizes profit by producing that quantity of output where
marginal revenue Marginal revenue (or marginal benefit) is a central concept in microeconomics that describes the additional total revenue generated by increasing product sales by 1 unit.Bradley R. chiller, "Essentials of Economics", New York: McGraw-Hill, Inc., ...
equals marginal costs. The profit maximization issue can also be approached from the input side. That is, what is the profit maximizing usage of the variable input? To maximize profits the firm should increase usage "up to the point where the input’s marginal revenue product equals its marginal costs". So, mathematically the profit maximizing rule is MRPL = MCL. The marginal profit per unit of labor equals the marginal revenue product of labor minus the marginal cost of labor or MπL = MRPL − MCLA firm maximizes profits where MπL = 0. The marginal revenue product is the change in total revenue per unit change in the variable input assume labor. That is, MRPL = ∆TR/∆L. MRPL is the product of marginal revenue and the marginal product of labor or MRPL = MR × MPL. *Derivation: :MR = ∆TR/∆Q :MPL = ∆Q/∆L :MRPL = MR × MPL = (∆TR/∆Q) × (∆Q/∆L) = ∆TR/∆L


Example

*Assume that the production function is Q = 90L - L^2 * MC_L = 30 *Output price is $40 per unit. : MP_L = 90 - 2L : MRP_L = 40(90 - 2L) : MRP_L = 3600 - 80L : MRP_L = MC_L (Profit Max Rule) : 3600 - 80L = 30 : 3570 = 80L : L = 44.625 :44.625 is the profit maximizing number of workers. : Q = 90L - L^2 : Q = 90(44.625) - (44.625)^2 : Q= 4016.25 - 1991.39 : Q = 2024.86 *Thus, the profit maximizing output is 2024.86 units, units might be given in thousands. Therefore quantity must not be discrete. *And the profit is : \Pi = TR - TC : TC = MC_L*L (Actually marginal cost of labor is wages paid for each worker. Therefore we get total cost if we multiply it by the quantity of labor not by the quantity of products) : \Pi = 40(2024.86) - 30(44.625) = 80994.4 - 1338.75 = 79655.65 * Some might be confused by the fact that L = 44.625 as intuition would say that labor should be discrete. Remember, however, that labor is actually a time measure as well. Thus, it can be thought of as a worker not working the entire hour.


Marginal productivity ethics

In the aftermath of the marginal revolution in economics, a number of economists including
John Bates Clark John Bates Clark (January 26, 1847 – March 21, 1938) was an American neoclassical economist. He was one of the pioneers of the marginalist revolution and opponent to the Institutionalist school of economics, and spent most of his career as ...
and
Thomas Nixon Carver Thomas Nixon Carver (25 March 1865 – 8 March 1961) was an American economics professor. Early life He grew up on a farm, the son of Quaker parents. He received an undergraduate education at Iowa Wesleyan College and the University of Southern ...
sought to derive an ethical theory of income distribution based on the idea that workers were morally entitled to receive a wage exactly equal to their marginal product. In the 20th century, marginal productivity ethics found few supporters among economists, being criticised not only by egalitarians but by economists associated with the Chicago school such as
Frank Knight Frank Hyneman Knight (November 7, 1885 – April 15, 1972) was an American economist who spent most of his career at the University of Chicago, where he became one of the founders of the Chicago School. Nobel laureates Milton Friedman, George ...
(in ''The Ethics of Competition'') and the
Austrian School The Austrian School is a heterodox school of economic thought that advocates strict adherence to methodological individualism, the concept that social phenomena result exclusively from the motivations and actions of individuals. Austrian schoo ...
, such as
Leland Yeager Leland Bennett Yeager (; October 4, 1924 – April 23, 2018) was an American economist dealing with monetary policy and international trade. Biography Yeager graduated from Oberlin College in 1948 with an A.B. and was granted an M.A. from Columb ...
. However, marginal productivity ethics were defended by
George Stigler George Joseph Stigler (; January 17, 1911 – December 1, 1991) was an American economist. He was the 1982 laureate in Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences and is considered a key leader of the Chicago school of economics. Early life and e ...
. A ''Review of Economics and Economic Methodology'' argues against pay to their
marginal product In economics and in particular neoclassical economics, the marginal product or marginal physical productivity of an input (factor of production) is the change in output resulting from employing one more unit of a particular input (for instance, th ...
to pay equal to the amount of their labor input''.'' This is known as the
Labor theory of value The labor theory of value (LTV) is a theory of value that argues that the economic value of a good or service is determined by the total amount of " socially necessary labor" required to produce it. The LTV is usually associated with Marxian ...
.
Marx Karl Heinrich Marx (; 5 May 1818 – 14 March 1883) was a German philosopher, economist, historian, sociologist, political theorist, journalist, critic of political economy, and socialist revolutionary. His best-known titles are the 1848 ...
characterizes the value of labor as a relationship between the person and things and how the perceived exchange of products is viewed socially. Alejandro Valle Baeza and Blanca Gloria Martínez González, Researchers compared productivity levels from countries that pay based of the marginal productivity and labor theory. The found that across countries, marginal productivity is more widely used than labor value, but when they measured productivity based on labor value, "productivity changes not only because of savings in both living labor and means of production, but it is also modified by changes in the productivity of these means of production."


See also

*
Marginal product of capital In economics, the marginal product of capital (MPK) is the additional production that a firm experiences when it adds an extra unit of capital. It is a feature of the production function, alongside the labour input. Definition The marginal produ ...


Footnotes


References

*Binger, B. and E. Hoffman, ''Microeconomics with Calculus'', 2nd ed. Addison-Wesley 1998, *Krugman, Paul, and Robin Wells (2009), ''Microeconomics'' 2d ed. Worth Publishers, *Nicholson, W., ''Microeconomic Theory'', 9th ed. Thomson 2005. *Nicholson, W. and C. Snyder, ''Intermediate Microeconomics'', Thomson 2007, *Perloff, J., ''Microeconomics Theory and Applications with Calculus'', Pearson 2008, *Pindyck, R. and D. Rubinfeld, ''Microeconomics'', 5th ed. Prentice-Hall 2001. *Samuelson, W. and S. Marks, ''Managerial Economics'', 4th ed. Wiley 2003. * Varian, Hal, ''Microeconomic Analysis'', 3rd ed. Norton 1992. *Baeza, A. V., & González, B. G. M. (2020). Labor Productivity and Marxist Theory of Labor Value. ''World Review of Political Economy'', ''11''(3), 377–387. https://doi.org/10.13169/worlrevipoliecon.11.3.0377 *Sen, A. (1978). On the labour theory of value: some methodological issues. ''Cambridge Journal of Economics'', ''2''(2), 175–190. http://www.jstor.org/stable/23596406 *Ellerman, D. (2017). Reframing the Labor Question: On Marginal Productivity Theory and the Labor Theory of Property. ''Review of Economics and Economic Methodology'', ''2''(1), 9–44. https://doi-org.ezproxy.uta.edu/http://www.reemslovenia.com/ {{DEFAULTSORT:Marginal Product Of Labor Production economics Marginal concepts de:Grenzprodukt der Arbeit