HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

Fair division is the problem in
game theory Game theory is the study of mathematical models of strategic interactions among rational agents. Myerson, Roger B. (1991). ''Game Theory: Analysis of Conflict,'' Harvard University Press, p.&nbs1 Chapter-preview links, ppvii–xi It has appli ...
of dividing a set of
resources Resource refers to all the materials available in our environment which are technologically accessible, economically feasible and culturally sustainable and help us to satisfy our needs and wants. Resources can broadly be classified upon their av ...
among several people who have an
entitlement An entitlement is a provision made in accordance with a legal framework of a society. Typically, entitlements are based on concepts of principle ("rights") which are themselves based in concepts of social equality or enfranchisement. In psycholo ...
to them so that each person receives their due share. That problem arises in various real-world settings such as division of inheritance, partnership dissolutions, divorce settlements, electronic
frequency allocation Frequency allocation (or spectrum allocation or spectrum management) is the allocation and regulation of the electromagnetic spectrum into radio frequency bands, normally done by governments in most countries. Because radio propagation does ...
, airport traffic management, and exploitation of Earth observation satellites. It is an active research area in
mathematics Mathematics is an area of knowledge that includes the topics of numbers, formulas and related structures, shapes and the spaces in which they are contained, and quantities and their changes. These topics are represented in modern mathematics ...
,
economics Economics () is the social science that studies the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services. Economics focuses on the behaviour and interactions of economic agents and how economies work. Microeconomics anal ...
(especially
social choice theory Social choice theory or social choice is a theoretical framework for analysis of combining individual opinions, preferences, interests, or welfares to reach a ''collective decision'' or ''social welfare'' in some sense.Amartya Sen (2008). "Soci ...
), dispute resolution, etc. The central tenet of fair division is that such a division should be performed by the players themselves, maybe using a
mediator Mediator may refer to: *A person who engages in mediation * Business mediator, a mediator in business * Vanishing mediator, a philosophical concept * Mediator variable, in statistics Chemistry and biology *Mediator (coactivator), a multiprotein ...
but certainly not an arbiter as only the players really know how they value the goods. The archetypal fair division
algorithm In mathematics and computer science, an algorithm () is a finite sequence of rigorous instructions, typically used to solve a class of specific problems or to perform a computation. Algorithms are used as specifications for performing ...
is
divide and choose Divide and choose (also Cut and choose or I cut, you choose) is a procedure for fair division of a continuous resource, such as a cake, between two parties. It involves a heterogeneous good or resource ("the cake") and two partners who have diffe ...
. It demonstrates that two agents with different tastes can divide a cake such that each of them believes that he got the best piece. The research in fair division can be seen as an extension of this procedure to various more complex settings. There are many different kinds of fair division problems, depending on the nature of goods to divide, the criteria for fairness, the nature of the players and their preferences, and other criteria for evaluating the quality of the division.


Things that can be divided

Formally, a fair division problem is defined by a set C (often called "the cake") and a group of n players. A division is a partition of C into n disjoint subsets: C = X_1 \sqcup X_2 \sqcup\cdots \sqcup X_n, one subset per player. The set C can be of various types: * C may be a finite set of indivisible items, for example: C = \, such that each item should be given entirely to a single person. * C may be an infinite set representing a divisible resource, for example: money, or a cake. Mathematically, a divisible resource is often modeled as a subset of a real space, for example, the section ,1may represent a long narrow cake, that has to be cut into parallel pieces. The
unit disk In mathematics, the open unit disk (or disc) around ''P'' (where ''P'' is a given point in the plane), is the set of points whose distance from ''P'' is less than 1: :D_1(P) = \.\, The closed unit disk around ''P'' is the set of points whose d ...
may represent an apple pie. Additionally, the set to be divided may be: * homogeneous – such as money, where only the amount matters, or * heterogeneous – such as a cake that may have different ingredients, different icings, etc. Finally, it is common to make some assumptions about whether the items to be divided are: * goods – such as a car or a cake, or * bads – such as house chores. Based on these distinctions, several general types of fair division problems have been studied: *
Fair item assignment Fair item allocation is a kind of a fair division problem in which the items to divide are ''discrete'' rather than continuous. The items have to be divided among several partners who value them differently, and each item has to be given as a whole ...
– dividing a set of ''indivisible and heterogeneous'' goods. * Fair resource allocation – dividing a set of ''divisible and homogeneous'' goods. A special case is
fair division of a single homogeneous resource Fair division of a single homogeneous resource is one of the simplest settings in fair division problems. There is a single resource that should be divided between several people. The challenge is that each person derives a different utility from e ...
. *
Fair cake-cutting Fair cake-cutting is a kind of fair division problem. The problem involves a ''heterogeneous'' resource, such as a cake with different toppings, that is assumed to be ''divisible'' – it is possible to cut arbitrarily small pieces of it without ...
– dividing a ''divisible, heterogeneous good''. A special case is when the cake is a circle; then the problem is called
fair pie-cutting The fair pie-cutting problem is a variation of the fair cake-cutting problem, in which the resource to be divided is circular. As an example, consider a birthday cake shaped as a disk. The cake should be divided among several children such that no ...
. * Fair
chore division Chore division is a fair division problem in which the divided resource is undesirable, so that each participant wants to get as little as possible. It is the mirror-image of the fair cake-cutting problem, in which the divided resource is desirable ...
– dividing a ''divisible, heterogeneous bad.'' Combinations and special cases are also common: * Rental harmony (aka the housemates problem) – dividing a set of ''indivisible heterogeneous goods'' (e.g., rooms in an apartment), and simultaneously a ''homogeneous divisible bad'' (the rent on the apartment). * Fair river sharing – dividing waters flowing in an international river among the countries along its stream. *
Fair random assignment Fair random assignment (also called probabilistic one-sided matching) is a kind of a fair division problem. In an ''assignment problem'' (also called '' house-allocation problem'' or '' one-sided matching''), there ''m'' objects and they have to be ...
– dividing lotteries over divisions – is especially common when allocating indivisible goods.


Definitions of fairness

Most of what is normally called a fair division is not considered so by the theory because of the use of
arbitration Arbitration is a form of alternative dispute resolution (ADR) that resolves disputes outside the judiciary courts. The dispute will be decided by one or more persons (the 'arbitrators', 'arbiters' or 'arbitral tribunal'), which renders the ...
. This kind of situation happens quite often with mathematical theories named after real life problems. The decisions in the
Talmud The Talmud (; he, , Talmūḏ) is the central text of Rabbinic Judaism and the primary source of Jewish religious law ('' halakha'') and Jewish theology. Until the advent of modernity, in nearly all Jewish communities, the Talmud was the ce ...
on
entitlement An entitlement is a provision made in accordance with a legal framework of a society. Typically, entitlements are based on concepts of principle ("rights") which are themselves based in concepts of social equality or enfranchisement. In psycholo ...
when an estate is
bankrupt Bankruptcy is a legal process through which people or other entities who cannot repay debts to creditors may seek relief from some or all of their debts. In most jurisdictions, bankruptcy is imposed by a court order, often initiated by the debtor ...
reflect some quite complex ideas about fairness, and most people would consider them fair. However they are the result of legal debates by rabbis rather than divisions according to the valuations of the claimants. According to the
Subjective theory of value The subjective theory of value is an economic theory which proposes the idea that the value of any good is not determined by the utility value of the object, nor by the cumulative value of components or labour needed to produce or manufacture it, ...
, there cannot be an objective measure of the value of each item. Therefore, ''objective fairness'' is not possible, as different people may assign different values to each item. Empirical experiments on how people define the concept of fairness lead to inconclusive results. Therefore, most current research on fairness focuses on concepts of ''subjective fairness''. Each of the n people is assumed to have a personal, subjective ''utility function'' or ''value function'', V_i, which assigns a numerical value to each subset of C. Often the functions are assumed to be normalized, so that every person values the empty set as 0 (V_i (\empty) = 0 for all i), and the entire set of items as 1 (V_i (C) = 1 for all i) if the items are desirable, and -1 if the items are undesirable. Examples are: * If C is the set of indivisible items , then
Alice Alice may refer to: * Alice (name), most often a feminine given name, but also used as a surname Literature * Alice (''Alice's Adventures in Wonderland''), a character in books by Lewis Carroll * ''Alice'' series, children's and teen books by ...
may assign a value of 1/3 to each item, which means that each item is important to her just the same as any other item. Bob may assign the value of 1 to the set , and the value 0 to all other sets except X; this means that he wants to get only the car and the apartment together; the car alone or the apartment alone, or each of them together with the piano, is worthless to him. * If C is a long narrow cake (modeled as the interval ,1, then, Alice may assign each subset a value proportional to its length, which means that she wants as much cake as possible, regardless of the icings. Bob may assign value only to subsets of .4, 0.6 for example, because this part of the cake contains cherries and Bob only cares about cherries. Based on these subjective value functions, there are a number of widely used criteria for a fair division. Some of these conflict with each other but often they can be combined. The criteria described here are only for when each player is entitled to the same amount: * A
proportional division A proportional division is a kind of fair division in which a resource is divided among ''n'' partners with subjective valuations, giving each partner at least 1/''n'' of the resource by his/her own subjective valuation. Proportionality was the f ...
means that every person gets at least his due share ''according to his own value function''. For instance if three people divide up a cake each gets at least a third by their own valuation, i.e. each of the ''n'' people gets a subset of ''C'' which he values as at least 1/''n'' of the total value: ** V_i(X_i) \ge V_i(C)/n for all i. * A super-proportional division is one where each player receives strictly more than 1/''n'' (such a division exists only if the players have different valuations): ** V_i(X_i) > V_i(C)/n for all ''i''. * An
envy-free Envy-freeness, also known as no-envy, is a criterion for fair division. It says that, when resources are allocated among people with equal rights, each person should receive a share that is, in their eyes, at least as good as the share received by a ...
division guarantees that no-one will want somebody else's share more than their own, i.e. every person gets a share that he values at least as much as all other shares: ** V_i(X_i) \ge V_i(X_j) for all i and j. * A group-envy-free division guarantees that no subset of agents envies another subset of the same size; it is much stronger than envy-freeness. * An equitable division means every person feels exactly the same happiness, i.e. the proportion of the cake a player receives by their own valuation is the same for every player. This is a difficult aim as players need not be truthful if asked their valuation: ** V_i(X_i) = V_j(X_j) for all i and j. * An
exact division Exact division, also called consensus division, is a partition of a continuous resource ("fair cake-cutting, cake") into some ''k'' pieces, such that each of ''n'' people with different tastes agree on the value of each of the pieces. For example, c ...
(aka consensus division) is one where all players agree on the value of each share : ** V_i(X_i) = V_j(X_i) for all i and j. All the above criteria assume that the participants have equal entitlements. If different participants have different entitlements (e.g., in a partnership where each partner invested a different amount), then the fairness criteria should be adapted accordingly. See Proportional cake-cutting with different entitlements.


Additional requirements

In addition to fairness, it is sometimes desired that the division be
Pareto optimal Pareto efficiency or Pareto optimality is a situation where no action or allocation is available that makes one individual better off without making another worse off. The concept is named after Vilfredo Pareto (1848–1923), Italian civil engin ...
, i.e., no other allocation would make someone better off without making someone else worse off. The term efficiency comes from the
economics Economics () is the social science that studies the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services. Economics focuses on the behaviour and interactions of economic agents and how economies work. Microeconomics anal ...
idea of the
efficient market The efficient-market hypothesis (EMH) is a hypothesis in financial economics that states that asset prices reflect all available information. A direct implication is that it is impossible to "beat the market" consistently on a risk-adjusted bas ...
. A division where one player gets everything is optimal by this definition so on its own this does not guarantee even a fair share. See also
efficient cake-cutting Efficient cake-cutting is a problem in economics and computer science. It involves a ''heterogeneous'' resource, such as a cake with different toppings or a land with different coverings, that is assumed to be ''divisible'' - it is possible to cut ...
and the
price of fairness In the theory of fair division, the price of fairness (POF) is the ratio of the largest economic welfare attainable by a division to the economic welfare attained by a ''fair'' division. The POF is a quantitative measure of the loss of welfare that ...
. In the real world people sometimes have a very accurate idea of how the other players value the goods and they may care very much about it. The case where they have complete knowledge of each other's valuations can be modeled by
game theory Game theory is the study of mathematical models of strategic interactions among rational agents. Myerson, Roger B. (1991). ''Game Theory: Analysis of Conflict,'' Harvard University Press, p.&nbs1 Chapter-preview links, ppvii–xi It has appli ...
. Partial knowledge is very hard to model. A major part of the practical side of fair division is the devising and study of procedures that work well despite such partial knowledge or small mistakes. An additional requirement is that the fair division procedure be a
truthful mechanism In game theory, an asymmetric game where players have private information is said to be strategy-proof or strategyproof (SP) if it is a weakly-dominant strategy for every player to reveal his/her private information, i.e. given no information about ...
, i.e., it should be a dominant strategy for the participants to report their true valuations. This requirement is usually very hard to satisfy in combination with fairness and Pareto-efficiency.


Procedures

A fair division procedure lists actions to be performed by the players in terms of the visible data and their valuations. A valid procedure is one that guarantees a fair division for every player who acts rationally according to their valuation. Where an action depends on a player's valuation the procedure is describing the
strategy Strategy (from Greek στρατηγία ''stratēgia'', "art of troop leader; office of general, command, generalship") is a general plan to achieve one or more long-term or overall goals under conditions of uncertainty. In the sense of the " ...
a rational player will follow. A player may act as if a piece had a different value but must be consistent. For instance if a procedure says the first player cuts the cake in two equal parts then the second player chooses a piece, then the first player cannot claim that the second player got more. What the players do is: * Agree on their criteria for a fair division * Select a valid procedure and follow its rules It is assumed the aim of each player is to maximize the minimum amount they might get, or in other words, to achieve the maximin. Procedures can be divided into ''discrete'' vs. ''continuous'' procedures. A discrete procedure would for instance only involve one person at a time cutting or marking a cake. Continuous procedures involve things like one player moving a knife and the other saying "stop". Another type of continuous procedure involves a person assigning a value to every part of the cake. For a list of fair division procedures, see :Fair division protocols. No finite protocol (even if unbounded) can guarantee an envy-free division of a cake among three or more players, if each player is to receive a single connected piece. However, this result applies only to the model presented in that work and not for cases where, for example, a mediator has full information of the players' valuation functions and proposes a division based on this information.


Extensions

Recently, the model of fair division has been extended from individual agents to ''families'' (pre-determined groups) of agents. See
Fair division among groups Fair division among groups (or families) is a class of fair division problems, in which the resources are allocated among ''groups'' of agents, rather than among individual agents. After the division, all members in each group consume the same sh ...
.


History

According to Sol Garfunkel, the cake-cutting problem had been one of the most important open problems in 20th century mathematics, when the most important variant of the problem was finally solved with the Brams-Taylor procedure by
Steven Brams Steven J. Brams (born November 28, 1940 in Concord, New Hampshire) is an American game theorist and political scientist at the New York University Department of Politics. Brams is best known for using the techniques of game theory, public choi ...
and Alan Taylor in 1995.
Divide and choose Divide and choose (also Cut and choose or I cut, you choose) is a procedure for fair division of a continuous resource, such as a cake, between two parties. It involves a heterogeneous good or resource ("the cake") and two partners who have diffe ...
's origins are undocumented. The related activities of
bargaining In the social sciences, bargaining or haggling is a type of negotiation in which the buyer and seller of a good or service debate the price or nature of a transaction. If the bargaining produces agreement on terms, the transaction takes p ...
and
barter In trade, barter (derived from ''baretor'') is a system of exchange in which participants in a transaction directly exchange goods or services for other goods or services without using a medium of exchange, such as money. Economists disti ...
are also ancient. Negotiations involving more than two people are also quite common, the
Potsdam Conference The Potsdam Conference (german: Potsdamer Konferenz) was held at Potsdam in the Soviet occupation zone from July 17 to August 2, 1945, to allow the three leading Allies to plan the postwar peace, while avoiding the mistakes of the Paris P ...
is a notable recent example. The theory of fair division dates back only to the end of the second world war. It was devised by a group of Polish mathematicians, Hugo Steinhaus, Bronisław Knaster and
Stefan Banach Stefan Banach ( ; 30 March 1892 – 31 August 1945) was a Polish mathematician who is generally considered one of the 20th century's most important and influential mathematicians. He was the founder of modern functional analysis, and an origina ...
, who used to meet in the
Scottish Café The Scottish Café ( pl, Kawiarnia Szkocka) was a café in Lwów, Poland (now Lviv, Ukraine) where, in the 1930s and 1940s, mathematicians from the Lwów School of Mathematics collaboratively discussed research problems, particularly in fun ...
in Lvov (then in Poland). A proportional (fair division) division for any number of players called 'last-diminisher' was devised in 1944. This was attributed to Banach and Knaster by Steinhaus when he made the problem public for the first time at a meeting of the
Econometric Society The Econometric Society is an international society of academic economists interested in applying statistical tools to their field. It is an independent organization with no connections to societies of professional mathematicians or statisticians. ...
in Washington D.C. on 17 September 1947. At that meeting he also proposed the problem of finding the smallest number of cuts necessary for such divisions. For the history of envy-free cake-cutting, see
envy-free cake-cutting An envy-free cake-cutting is a kind of fair cake-cutting. It is a division of a heterogeneous resource ("cake") that satisfies the envy-free criterion, namely, that every partner feels that their allocated share is at least as good as any other sha ...
.


In popular culture

* In ''
Numb3rs ''Numbers'' (stylized as ''NUMB3RS'') is an American crime drama television series that was broadcast on CBS from January 23, 2005, to March 12, 2010, for six seasons and 118 episodes. The series was created by Nicolas Falacci and Cheryl Heu ...
'' season 3 episode "One Hour", Charlie talks about the cake-cutting problem as applied to the amount of money a kidnapper was demanding. * Hugo Steinhaus wrote about a number of variants of fair division in his book ''Mathematical Snapshots''. In his book he says a special three-person version of fair division was devised by G. Krochmainy in Berdechów in 1944 and another by Mrs L Kott. *
Martin Gardner Martin Gardner (October 21, 1914May 22, 2010) was an American popular mathematics and popular science writer with interests also encompassing scientific skepticism, micromagic, philosophy, religion, and literatureespecially the writings of Lew ...
and Ian Stewart have both published books with sections about the problem. Martin Gardner introduced the chore division form of the problem. Ian Stewart has popularized the fair division problem with his articles in ''
Scientific American ''Scientific American'', informally abbreviated ''SciAm'' or sometimes ''SA'', is an American popular science magazine. Many famous scientists, including Albert Einstein and Nikola Tesla, have contributed articles to it. In print since 1845, it ...
'' and ''
New Scientist ''New Scientist'' is a magazine covering all aspects of science and technology. Based in London, it publishes weekly English-language editions in the United Kingdom, the United States and Australia. An editorially separate organisation publish ...
''. * A ''
Dinosaur Comics ''Dinosaur Comics'' is a constrained comics, constrained webcomic by Canadian writer Ryan North. It is also known as "Qwantz", after the site's domain name, "qwantz.com". The first comic was posted on February 1, 2003, although there were earlier ...
'' strip is based on the cake-cutting problem. * In the Israeli movie Saint Clara, a Russian immigrant asks an Israeli math teacher, how a circular cake can be divided fairly among 7 people? His answer is to make 3 straight cuts through its middle, making 8 equal pieces. Since there are only 7 people, one piece should be discarded, in the spirit of communism.


See also

* Online fair division is a variant of fair division in which not all items or agents are available at the time of division. *
Equity (economics) Equity, or economic equality, is the concept or idea of fairness in economics, particularly in regard to taxation or welfare economics. More specifically, it may refer to a movement that strives to provide equal life chances regardless of iden ...
*
International trade International trade is the exchange of capital, goods, and services across international borders or territories because there is a need or want of goods or services. (see: World economy) In most countries, such trade represents a significa ...
* Justice (economics) *
Knapsack problem The knapsack problem is a problem in combinatorial optimization: Given a set of items, each with a weight and a value, determine the number of each item to include in a collection so that the total weight is less than or equal to a given limit a ...
* List of unsolved problems in fair division *
Nash bargaining game Cooperative bargaining is a process in which two people decide how to share a surplus that they can jointly generate. In many cases, the surplus created by the two players can be shared in many ways, forcing the players to negotiate which division o ...
* Pizza theorem *
Price of fairness In the theory of fair division, the price of fairness (POF) is the ratio of the largest economic welfare attainable by a division to the economic welfare attained by a ''fair'' division. The POF is a quantitative measure of the loss of welfare that ...
* Spite (game theory) * Strategic fair division *
Tragedy of the anticommons The tragedy of the anticommons is a type of coordination breakdown, in which a commons does not emerge, even when general access to resources or infrastructure would be a social good. It is a mirror-image of the older concept of tragedy of the co ...
*
Tragedy of the commons Tragedy (from the grc-gre, τραγῳδία, ''tragōidia'', ''tragōidia'') is a genre of drama based on human suffering and, mainly, the terrible or sorrowful events that befall a main character. Traditionally, the intention of tragedy i ...


References


Text books

* * * * * *


Survey articles

* Vincent P. Crawford (1987). "fair division," ''The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics'', v. 2, pp. 274–75. *
Hal Varian Hal Ronald Varian (born March 18, 1947 in Wooster, Ohio) is Chief Economist at Google and holds the title of emeritus professor at the University of California, Berkeley where he was founding dean of the School of Information. Varian is an eco ...
(1987). "fairness," ''The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics'', v. 2, pp. 275–76. * Bryan Skyrms (1996). ''The Evolution of the Social Contract'' Cambridge University Press. * * , chapters 11–13.
Fair Division
by Christian Klamler – in Handbook of Group Decision and Negotiation pp 183–202.
Cake-Cutting: Fair Division of Divisible Goods
by Claudia Lindner and Jörg Rothe – in Economics and Computation pp 395–491.
Fair division of indivisible goods
by Jérôme Lang and Jörg Rothe – in Economics and Computation pp 493–550.


External links



from the Discrete Mathematics Project at the University of Colorado at Boulder.
Fair Division: Method of Markers

Fair Division: Method of Sealed Bids
{{DEFAULTSORT:Fair Division Game theory Welfare economics