constant elasticity of substitution
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

Constant elasticity of substitution (CES), in
economics Economics () is the social science that studies the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services. Economics focuses on the behaviour and interactions of economic agents and how economies work. Microeconomics analyzes ...
, is a property of some
production function In economics, a production function gives the technological relation between quantities of physical inputs and quantities of output of goods. The production function is one of the key concepts of mainstream neoclassical theories, used to define ...
s and
utility function As a topic of economics, utility is used to model worth or value. Its usage has evolved significantly over time. The term was introduced initially as a measure of pleasure or happiness as part of the theory of utilitarianism by moral philosoph ...
s. Several economists have featured in the topic and have contributed in the final finding of the constant. They include Tom McKenzie,
John Hicks Sir John Richards Hicks (8 April 1904 – 20 May 1989) was a British economist. He is considered one of the most important and influential economists of the twentieth century. The most familiar of his many contributions in the field of economi ...
and
Joan Robinson Joan Violet Robinson (''née'' Maurice; 31 October 1903 – 5 August 1983) was a British economist well known for her wide-ranging contributions to economic theory. She was a central figure in what became known as post-Keynesian economics. B ...
. The vital economic element of the measure is that it provided the producer a clear picture of how to move between different modes or types of production. Specifically, it arises in a particular type of aggregator function which combines two or more types of consumption goods, or two or more types of production inputs into an aggregate quantity. This aggregator function exhibits constant
elasticity of substitution Elasticity of substitution is the ratio of percentage change in capital-labour ratio with the percentage change in Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution. In a competitive market, it measures the percentage change in the two inputs used in respons ...
.


CES production function

Despite having several factors of production in substitutability, the most common are the forms of elasticity of substitution. On the contrary of restricting direct empirical evaluation, the constant Elasticity of Substitution are simple to use and hence are widely used. McFadden states that;
The constant E.S assumption is a restriction on the form of production possibilities, and one can characterize the class of production functions which have this property. This has been done by Arrow-Chenery-Minhas-Solow for the two-factor production case.
The CES
production function In economics, a production function gives the technological relation between quantities of physical inputs and quantities of output of goods. The production function is one of the key concepts of mainstream neoclassical theories, used to define ...
is a neoclassical production function that displays constant
elasticity of substitution Elasticity of substitution is the ratio of percentage change in capital-labour ratio with the percentage change in Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution. In a competitive market, it measures the percentage change in the two inputs used in respons ...
. In other words, the production technology has a constant percentage change in factor (e.g. labour and capital) proportions due to a percentage change in
marginal rate of technical substitution In microeconomic theory, the marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS)—or technical rate of substitution (TRS)—is the amount by which the quantity of one input has to be reduced (-\Delta x_2) when one extra unit of another input is used ( ...
. The two factor (capital, labor) CES production function introduced by Solow, and later made popular by Arrow, Chenery,
Minhas The Minhas or Manhas is a Rajput Clan. They are found in Punjab, Himachal Pradesh and Jammu and Kashmir. These are spread in most of the part of Gagwan and Jhatgali of district Ramban. It is found in Hindu, Muslim and Sikh communities. Notabl ...
, and Solow is: :Q = F\cdot \left(a \cdot K^\rho+(1-a) \cdot L^\rho\right)^ where * Q = Quantity of output * F = Factor productivity * a = Share parameter * K, L = Quantities of primary production factors (Capital and Labor) * \rho = = Substitution parameter * \sigma = =
Elasticity of substitution Elasticity of substitution is the ratio of percentage change in capital-labour ratio with the percentage change in Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution. In a competitive market, it measures the percentage change in the two inputs used in respons ...
* \upsilon = degree of homogeneity of the production function. Where \upsilon = 1 (Constant return to scale), \upsilon < 1 (Decreasing return to scale), \upsilon > 1 (Increasing return to scale). As its name suggests, the CES production function exhibits constant elasticity of substitution between capital and labor. Leontief, linear and Cobb–Douglas functions are special cases of the CES production function. That is, * If \rho approaches 1, we have a
linear Linearity is the property of a mathematical relationship ('' function'') that can be graphically represented as a straight line. Linearity is closely related to '' proportionality''. Examples in physics include rectilinear motion, the linear ...
or perfect substitutes function; * If \rho approaches zero in the limit, we get the
Cobb–Douglas production function In economics and econometrics, the Cobb–Douglas production function is a particular functional form of the production function, widely used to represent the technological relationship between the amounts of two or more inputs (particularly phy ...
; * If \rho approaches negative infinity we get the
Leontief Wassily Wassilyevich Leontief (russian: Васи́лий Васи́льевич Лео́нтьев; August 5, 1905 – February 5, 1999), was a Soviet-American economist known for his research on Input–output model, input–output analysis and ...
or perfect complements production function. The general form of the CES production function, with ''n'' inputs, is: : Q = F \cdot \left sum_^n a_X_^\ \right where * Q = Quantity of output * F = Factor productivity * a_ = Share parameter of input i, \sum_^n a_ = 1 * X_i = Quantities of factors of production (i = 1,2...n) * s=\frac = Elasticity of substitution. Extending the CES (Solow) functional form to accommodate multiple factors of production creates some problems. However, there is no completely general way to do this. Uzawa showed the only possible n-factor production functions (n>2) with constant partial elasticities of substitution require either that all elasticities between pairs of factors be identical, or if any differ, these all must equal each other and all remaining elasticities must be unity. This is true for any production function. This means the use of the CES functional form for more than 2 factors will generally mean that there is not constant elasticity of substitution among all factors. Nested CES functions are commonly found in
partial equilibrium In economics, partial equilibrium is a condition of economic equilibrium which analyzes only a single market, ''ceteris paribus'' (everything else remaining constant) except for the one change at a time being analyzed. In general equilibrium ana ...
and
general equilibrium In economics, general equilibrium theory attempts to explain the behavior of supply, demand, and prices in a whole economy with several or many interacting markets, by seeking to prove that the interaction of demand and supply will result in an ov ...
models. Different nests (levels) allow for the introduction of the appropriate elasticity of substitution.


CES utility function

The same CES functional form arises as a utility function in
consumer theory The theory of consumer choice is the branch of microeconomics that relates preferences to consumption expenditures and to consumer demand curves. It analyzes how consumers maximize the desirability of their consumption as measured by their pref ...
. For example, if there exist n types of consumption goods x_i, then aggregate consumption X could be defined using the CES aggregator: : X = \left sum_^n a_^x_^\ \right. Here again, the coefficients a_i are share parameters, and s is the elasticity of substitution. Therefore, the consumption goods x_i are perfect substitutes when s approaches infinity and perfect complements when s approaches zero. In the case where s approaches one is again a limiting case where
L'Hôpital's Rule In calculus, l'Hôpital's rule or l'Hospital's rule (, , ), also known as Bernoulli's rule, is a theorem which provides a technique to evaluate limits of indeterminate forms. Application (or repeated application) of the rule often converts an i ...
applies. The CES aggregator is also sometimes called the ''Armington aggregator'', which was discussed by Armington (1969). CES utility functions are a special case of
homothetic preferences In consumer theory, a consumer's preferences are called homothetic if they can be represented by a utility function which is homogeneous of degree 1. For example, in an economy with two goods x,y, homothetic preferences can be represented by a ut ...
. The following is an example of a CES utility function for two goods, x and y, with equal shares: :u(x,y) =(x^r + y^r)^. The
expenditure function In microeconomics, the expenditure function gives the minimum amount of money an individual needs to spend to achieve some level of utility, given a utility function and the prices of the available goods. Formally, if there is a utility function u ...
in this case is: :e(p_x,p_y,u) =(p_x^ + p_y^)^ \cdot u. The
indirect utility function __NOTOC__ In economics, a consumer's indirect utility function v(p, w) gives the consumer's maximal attainable utility when faced with a vector p of goods prices and an amount of income w. It reflects both the consumer's preferences and market con ...
is its inverse: :v(p_x,p_y,I) =(p_x^ + p_y^)^ \cdot I. The
demand function In economics, a demand curve is a graph depicting the relationship between the price of a certain commodity (the ''y''-axis) and the quantity of that commodity that is demanded at that price (the ''x''-axis). Demand curves can be used either for ...
s are: :x(p_x,p_y,I) = \frac\cdot I, :y(p_x,p_y,I) = \frac\cdot I. A CES utility function is one of the cases considered by Dixit and Stiglitz (1977) in their study of optimal product diversity in a context of
monopolistic competition Monopolistic competition is a type of imperfect competition such that there are many producers competing against each other, but selling products that are differentiated from one another (e.g. by branding or quality) and hence are not perfec ...
. Note the difference between CES utility and
isoelastic utility In economics, the isoelastic function for utility, also known as the isoelastic utility function, or power utility function, is used to express utility in terms of consumption or some other economic variable that a decision-maker is concerned with ...
: the CES utility function is an
ordinal utility In economics, an ordinal utility function is a function representing the preferences of an agent on an ordinal scale. Ordinal utility theory claims that it is only meaningful to ask which option is better than the other, but it is meaningless to a ...
function that represents preferences on sure consumption commodity bundles, while the isoelastic utility function is a
cardinal utility In economics, a cardinal utility function or scale is a utility index that preserves preference orderings uniquely up to positive affine transformations. Two utility indices are related by an affine transformation if for the value u(x_i) of one i ...
function that represents preferences on lotteries. A CES indirect (dual) utility function has been used to derive utility-consistent brand demand systems where category demands are determined endogenously by a multi-category, CES indirect (dual) utility function. It has also been shown that CES preferences are self-dual and that both primal and dual CES preferences yield systems of indifference curves that may exhibit any degree of convexity.


References

{{reflist


External links


Anatomy of CES Type Production Functions in 3DClosed form solution for a firm with an N-dimensional CES technologyMonopolists revenue function
Production economics Econometric modeling Elasticity (economics) Utility function types