HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

The Solow–Swan model or exogenous growth model is an
economic model In economics, a model is a theoretical construct representing economic processes by a set of variables and a set of logical and/or quantitative relationships between them. The economic model is a simplified, often mathematical, framework desi ...
of long-run
economic growth Economic growth can be defined as the increase or improvement in the inflation-adjusted market value of the goods and services produced by an economy in a financial year. Statisticians conventionally measure such growth as the percent rate o ...
. It attempts to explain long-run economic growth by looking at
capital accumulation Capital accumulation is the dynamic that motivates the pursuit of profit, involving the investment of money or any financial asset with the goal of increasing the initial monetary value of said asset as a financial return whether in the form ...
, labor or
population growth Population growth is the increase in the number of people in a population or dispersed group. Actual global human population growth amounts to around 83 million annually, or 1.1% per year. The global population has grown from 1 billion in 1800 to ...
, and increases in
productivity Productivity is the efficiency of production of goods or services expressed by some measure. Measurements of productivity are often expressed as a ratio of an aggregate output to a single input or an aggregate input used in a production proces ...
largely driven by
technological progress Technology is the application of knowledge to reach practical goals in a specifiable and reproducible way. The word ''technology'' may also mean the product of such an endeavor. The use of technology is widely prevalent in medicine, science, ...
. At its core, it is an aggregate
production function In economics, a production function gives the technological relation between quantities of physical inputs and quantities of output of goods. The production function is one of the key concepts of mainstream neoclassical theories, used to define ...
, often specified to be of Cobb–Douglas type, which enables the model "to make contact with
microeconomics Microeconomics is a branch of mainstream economics that studies the behavior of individuals and firms in making decisions regarding the allocation of scarce resources and the interactions among these individuals and firms. Microeconomics fo ...
". The model was developed independently by
Robert Solow Robert Merton Solow, GCIH (; born August 23, 1924) is an American economist whose work on the theory of economic growth culminated in the exogenous growth model named after him. He is currently Emeritus Institute Professor of Economics at th ...
and Trevor Swan in 1956,The idea of using a Cobb–Douglas production function at the core of a growth model dates back to . See and superseded the
Keynesian Keynesian economics ( ; sometimes Keynesianism, named after British economist John Maynard Keynes) are the various macroeconomic theories and models of how aggregate demand (total spending in the economy) strongly influences economic output an ...
Harrod–Domar model. Mathematically, the Solow–Swan model is a
nonlinear system In mathematics and science, a nonlinear system is a system in which the change of the output is not proportional to the change of the input. Nonlinear problems are of interest to engineers, biologists, physicists, mathematicians, and many othe ...
consisting of a single
ordinary differential equation In mathematics, an ordinary differential equation (ODE) is a differential equation whose unknown(s) consists of one (or more) function(s) of one variable and involves the derivatives of those functions. The term ''ordinary'' is used in contrast ...
that models the evolution of the ''
per capita ''Per capita'' is a Latin phrase literally meaning "by heads" or "for each head", and idiomatically used to mean "per person". The term is used in a wide variety of social sciences and statistical research contexts, including government statistic ...
'' stock of capital. Due to its particularly attractive mathematical characteristics, Solow–Swan proved to be a convenient starting point for various extensions. For instance, in 1965, David Cass and
Tjalling Koopmans Tjalling Charles Koopmans (August 28, 1910 – February 26, 1985) was a Dutch-American mathematician and economist. He was the joint winner with Leonid Kantorovich of the 1975 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences for his work on the theory ...
integrated Frank Ramsey's analysis of consumer optimization, thereby endogenizing the saving rate, to create what is now known as the
Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model The Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model, or Ramsey growth model, is a neoclassical model of economic growth based primarily on the work of Frank P. Ramsey, with significant extensions by David Cass and Tjalling Koopmans. The Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans ...
.


Background

The Solow–Swan model was an extension to the 1946 Harrod–Domar model that dropped the restrictive assumption that only capital contributes to growth (so long as there is sufficient labor to use all capital). Important contributions to the model came from the work done by Solow and by Swan in 1956, who independently developed relatively simple growth models.Pdf.
/ref> Solow's model fitted available data on US economic growth with some success. In 1987 Solow was awarded the
Nobel Prize in Economics The Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences, officially the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel ( sv, Sveriges riksbanks pris i ekonomisk vetenskap till Alfred Nobels minne), is an economics award administered ...
for his work. Today, economists use Solow's sources-of-growth accounting to estimate the separate effects on economic growth of technological change, capital, and labor. The Solow model is also one of the most widely used models in economics to explain economic growth. Basically, it asserts that outcomes on the "total factor productivity (TFP) can lead to limitless increases in the standard of living in a country."


Extension to the Harrod–Domar model

Solow extended the Harrod–Domar model by adding labor as a
factor of production In economics, factors of production, resources, or inputs are what is used in the production process to produce output—that is, goods and services. The utilized amounts of the various inputs determine the quantity of output according to the rel ...
and capital-output ratios that are not fixed as they are in the Harrod–Domar model. These refinements allow increasing
capital intensity Capital intensity is the amount of fixed or real capital present in relation to other factors of production, especially labor. At the level of either a production process or the aggregate economy, it may be estimated by the capital to labor ratio, ...
to be distinguished from technological progress. Solow sees the fixed proportions production function as a "crucial assumption" to the instability results in the Harrod-Domar model. His own work expands upon this by exploring the implications of alternative specifications, namely the Cobb–Douglas and the more general constant elasticity of substitution (CES). Although this has become the canonical and celebrated story in the history of economics, featured in many economic textbooks, recent reappraisal of Harrod's work has contested it. One central criticism is that Harrod's original piece was neither mainly concerned with economic growth nor did he explicitly use a fixed proportions production function.


Long-run implications

A standard Solow model predicts that in the long run, economies converge to their
steady state In systems theory, a system or a process is in a steady state if the variables (called state variables) which define the behavior of the system or the process are unchanging in time. In continuous time, this means that for those properties ''p' ...
equilibrium and that permanent growth is achievable only through technological progress. Both shifts in saving and in populational growth cause only level effects in the long-run (i.e. in the absolute value of real income per capita). An interesting implication of Solow's model is that poor countries should grow faster and eventually catch-up to richer countries. This
convergence Convergence may refer to: Arts and media Literature *''Convergence'' (book series), edited by Ruth Nanda Anshen *Convergence (comics), "Convergence" (comics), two separate story lines published by DC Comics: **A four-part crossover storyline that ...
could be explained by: * Lags in the diffusion on knowledge. Differences in real income might shrink as poor countries receive better technology and information; * Efficient allocation of international capital flows, since the rate of return on capital should be higher in poorer countries. In practice, this is seldom observed and is known as Lucas' paradox; * A mathematical implication of the model (assuming poor countries have not yet reached their steady state). Baumol attempted to verify this empirically and found a very strong correlation between a countries' output growth over a long period of time (1870 to 1979) and its initial wealth. His findings were later contested by DeLong who claimed that both the non-randomness of the sampled countries, and potential for significant measurement errors for estimates of real income per capita in 1870, biased Baumol's findings. DeLong concludes that there is little evidence to support the convergence theory.


Assumptions

The key assumption of the Solow–Swan growth model is that capital is subject to
diminishing returns In economics, diminishing returns are the decrease in marginal (incremental) output of a production process as the amount of a single factor of production is incrementally increased, holding all other factors of production equal ( ceteris pari ...
in a closed economy. *Given a fixed stock of labor, the impact on output of the last unit of capital accumulated will always be less than the one before. *Assuming for simplicity no technological progress or labor force growth, diminishing returns implies that at some point the amount of new capital produced is only just enough to make up for the amount of existing capital lost due to depreciation. At this point, because of the assumptions of no technological progress or labor force growth, we can see the economy ceases to grow. *Assuming non-zero rates of labor growth complicate matters somewhat, but the basic logic still applies – in the short-run, the rate of growth slows as diminishing returns take effect and the economy converges to a constant "steady-state" rate of growth (that is, ''no'' economic growth per-capita). *Including non-zero technological progress is very similar to the assumption of non-zero workforce growth, in terms of "effective labor": a new steady state is reached with constant output per ''worker-hour required for a unit of output''. However, in this case, per-capita output grows at the rate of technological progress in the "steady-state" (that is, the rate of
productivity Productivity is the efficiency of production of goods or services expressed by some measure. Measurements of productivity are often expressed as a ratio of an aggregate output to a single input or an aggregate input used in a production proces ...
growth).


Variations in the effects of productivity

In the Solow–Swan model the unexplained change in the growth of output after accounting for the effect of capital accumulation is called the
Solow residual The Solow residual is a number describing empirical productivity growth in an economy from year to year and decade to decade. Robert Solow, the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences-winning economist, defined rising productivity as rising outpu ...
. This residual measures the exogenous increase in
total factor productivity In economics, total-factor productivity (TFP), also called multi-factor productivity, is usually measured as the ratio of aggregate output (e.g., GDP) to aggregate inputs. Under some simplifying assumptions about the production technology, grow ...
(TFP) during a particular time period. The increase in TFP is often attributed entirely to technological progress, but it also includes any permanent improvement in the efficiency with which factors of production are combined over time. Implicitly TFP growth includes any permanent productivity improvements that result from improved management practices in the private or public sectors of the economy. Paradoxically, even though TFP growth is exogenous in the model, it cannot be observed, so it can only be estimated in conjunction with the simultaneous estimate of the effect of capital accumulation on growth during a particular time period. The model can be reformulated in slightly different ways using different productivity assumptions, or different measurement metrics: *Average Labor Productivity (ALP) is economic output per labor hour. *
Multifactor productivity In economics, total-factor productivity (TFP), also called multi-factor productivity, is usually measured as the ratio of aggregate output (e.g., GDP) to aggregate inputs. Under some simplifying assumptions about the production technology, growt ...
(MFP) is output divided by a weighted average of capital and labor inputs. The weights used are usually based on the aggregate input shares either factor earns. This ratio is often quoted as: 33% return to capital and 67% return to labor (in Western nations). In a growing economy, capital is accumulated faster than people are born, so the denominator in the growth function under the MFP calculation is growing faster than in the ALP calculation. Hence, MFP growth is almost always lower than ALP growth. (Therefore, measuring in ALP terms increases the apparent
capital deepening Capital deepening is a situation where the capital per worker is increasing in the economy. This is also referred to as increase in the capital intensity. Capital deepening is often measured by the rate of change in capital stock per labour hou ...
effect.) MFP is measured by the "
Solow residual The Solow residual is a number describing empirical productivity growth in an economy from year to year and decade to decade. Robert Solow, the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences-winning economist, defined rising productivity as rising outpu ...
", not ALP.


Mathematics of the model

The textbook Solow–Swan model is set in
continuous-time In mathematical dynamics, discrete time and continuous time are two alternative frameworks within which variables that evolve over time are modeled. Discrete time Discrete time views values of variables as occurring at distinct, separate "po ...
world with no government or international trade. A single
good In most contexts, the concept of good denotes the conduct that should be preferred when posed with a choice between possible actions. Good is generally considered to be the opposite of evil and is of interest in the study of ethics, morality, ph ...
(output) is produced using two
factors of production In economics, factors of production, resources, or inputs are what is used in the production process to produce output—that is, goods and services. The utilized amounts of the various inputs determine the quantity of output according to the rel ...
, labor (L) and capital (K) in an aggregate production function that satisfies the
Inada conditions In macroeconomics, the Inada conditions, named after Japanese economist Ken-Ichi Inada, are assumptions about the shape of a function, usually applied to a production function or a utility function. When the production function of a neoclassica ...
, which imply that the elasticity of substitution must be asymptotically equal to one. : Y(t)=K(t)^\alpha(A(t)L(t))^\, where t denotes time, 0 < \alpha < 1 is the elasticity of output with respect to capital, and Y(t) represents total production. A refers to labor-augmenting technology or “
knowledge Knowledge can be defined as awareness of facts or as practical skills, and may also refer to familiarity with objects or situations. Knowledge of facts, also called propositional knowledge, is often defined as true belief that is distin ...
”, thus AL represents effective labor. All factors of production are fully employed, and initial values A(0), K(0), and L(0) are given. The number of workers, i.e. labor, as well as the level of technology grow exogenously at rates n and g, respectively: :L(t) = L(0)e^ :A(t) = A(0)e^ The number of effective units of labor, A(t)L(t), therefore grows at rate (n+g). Meanwhile, the
stock In finance, stock (also capital stock) consists of all the shares by which ownership of a corporation or company is divided.Longman Business English Dictionary: "stock - ''especially AmE'' one of the shares into which ownership of a compan ...
of capital depreciates over time at a constant rate \delta. However, only a fraction of the output (cY(t) with 0) is consumed, leaving a saved share s = 1-c for
investment Investment is the dedication of money to purchase of an asset to attain an increase in value over a period of time. Investment requires a sacrifice of some present asset, such as time, money, or effort. In finance, the purpose of investing is ...
. This dynamic is expressed through the following
differential equation In mathematics, a differential equation is an equation that relates one or more unknown functions and their derivatives. In applications, the functions generally represent physical quantities, the derivatives represent their rates of change, ...
: :\dot(t) = s \cdot Y(t) - \delta \cdot K(t)\, where \dot is shorthand for \frac, the derivative with respect to time. Derivative with respect to time means that it is the change in capital stock—output that is neither consumed nor used to replace worn-out old capital goods is net investment. Since the production function Y(K, AL) has constant
returns to scale In economics, returns to scale describe what happens to long-run returns as the scale of production increases, when all input levels including physical capital usage are variable (able to be set by the firm). The concept of returns to scale arises ...
, it can be written as ''output per effective unit of labour'' y, which is a measure for wealth creation:Step-by-step calculation: y(t) = \frac = \frac = \frac = k(t)^ :y(t) = \frac = k(t)^\alpha The main interest of the model is the dynamics of
capital intensity Capital intensity is the amount of fixed or real capital present in relation to other factors of production, especially labor. At the level of either a production process or the aggregate economy, it may be estimated by the capital to labor ratio, ...
k, the capital stock per unit of effective labour. Its behaviour over time is given by the key equation of the Solow–Swan model:Step-by-step calculation: \dot(t) = \frac - \frac (t)\dot(t)+L(t)\dot(t)= \frac - \frac \frac - \frac \frac. Since \dot(t) = sY(t) - \delta K(t)\,, and \frac, \frac are n and g, respectively, the equation simplifies to \dot(t) = s\frac - \delta\frac - n\frac - g\frac = sy(t) - \delta k(t) - nk(t) - gk(t). As mentioned above, y(t) = k(t)^\alpha. :\dot(t) = sk(t)^ - (n + g + \delta)k(t) The first term, sk(t)^ = sy(t), is the actual investment per unit of effective labour: the fraction s of the output per unit of effective labour y(t) that is saved and invested. The second term, (n + g + \delta)k(t), is the “break-even investment”: the amount of investment that must be invested to prevent k from falling. The equation implies that k(t) converges to a steady-state value of k^*, defined by sk(t)^ = (n + g + \delta)k(t), at which there is neither an increase nor a decrease of capital intensity: :k^* = \left( \frac \right)^ \, at which the stock of capital K and effective labour AL are growing at rate (n + g). Likewise, it is possible to calculate the steady-state of created wealth y^* that corresponds with k^*: :y^* = \left( \frac \right)^ \, By assumption of constant returns, output Y is also growing at that rate. In essence, the Solow–Swan model predicts that an economy will converge to a balanced-growth equilibrium, regardless of its starting point. In this situation, the growth of output per worker is determined solely by the rate of
technological progress Technology is the application of knowledge to reach practical goals in a specifiable and reproducible way. The word ''technology'' may also mean the product of such an endeavor. The use of technology is widely prevalent in medicine, science, ...
. Since, by definition, \frac = k(t)^ , at the equilibrium k^* we have :\frac = \frac Therefore, at the equilibrium, the capital/output ratio depends only on the saving, growth, and depreciation rates. This is the Solow–Swan model's version of the golden rule saving rate. Since <1, at any time t the marginal product of capital K(t) in the Solow–Swan model is inversely related to the capital/labor ratio. :MPK=\frac= \frac If productivity A is the same across countries, then countries with less capital per worker K/L have a higher marginal product, which would provide a higher return on capital investment. As a consequence, the model predicts that in a world of open market economies and global financial capital, investment will flow from rich countries to poor countries, until capital/worker K/L and income/worker Y/L equalize across countries. Since the marginal product of physical capital is not higher in poor countries than in rich countries, the implication is that productivity is lower in poor countries. The basic Solow model cannot explain why productivity is lower in these countries. Lucas suggested that lower levels of human capital in poor countries could explain the lower productivity. Because the
marginal product of capital In economics, the marginal product of capital (MPK) is the additional production that a firm experiences when it adds an extra unit of capital. It is a feature of the production function, alongside the labour input. Definition The marginal produ ...
\frac equals the
rate of return In finance, return is a profit on an investment. It comprises any change in value of the investment, and/or cash flows (or securities, or other investments) which the investor receives from that investment, such as interest payments, coupons, cas ...
r : \alpha = \frac = \frac \, so that \alpha is the fraction of income appropriated by capital. Thus, the Solow–Swan model assumes from the beginning that the labor-capital split of income is constant.


Mankiw–Romer–Weil version of model


Addition of human capital

N. Gregory Mankiw Nicholas Gregory Mankiw (; born February 3, 1958) is an American macroeconomist who is currently the Robert M. Beren Professor of Economics at Harvard University. Mankiw is best known in academia for his work on New Keynesian economics. Mankiw ...
,
David Romer David Hibbard Romer (born March 13, 1958) is an American economist, the Herman Royer Professor of Political Economy at the University of California, Berkeley, and the author of a standard textbook in graduate macroeconomics as well as many influ ...
, and
David Weil David Weil is an American academic and economist who was the nominee to serve as administrator of the Wage and Hour Division at the United States Department of Labor in the Biden administration. He previously served in this role during the Obama ...
created a
human capital Human capital is a concept used by social scientists to designate personal attributes considered useful in the production process. It encompasses employee knowledge, skills, know-how, good health, and education. Human capital has a substantial ...
augmented version of the Solow–Swan model that can explain the failure of international investment to flow to poor countries. In this model output and the marginal product of capital (K) are lower in poor countries because they have less human capital than rich countries. Similar to the textbook Solow–Swan model, the production function is of Cobb–Douglas type: : Y(t) = K(t)^\alpha H(t)^\beta (A(t)L(t))^, where H(t) is the stock of human capital, which depreciates at the same rate \delta as physical capital. For simplicity, they assume the same function of accumulation for both types of capital. Like in Solow–Swan, a fraction of the outcome, sY(t), is saved each period, but in this case split up and invested partly in physical and partly in human capital, such that s = s_K + s_H. Therefore, there are two fundamental dynamic equations in this model: :\dot = s_K k^\alpha h^\beta - (n + g + \delta)k :\dot = s_H k^\alpha h^\beta - (n + g + \delta)h The balanced (or steady-state) equilibrium growth path is determined by \dot = \dot = 0, which means s_K k^\alpha h^\beta - (n + g + \delta)k = 0 and s_H k^\alpha h^\beta - (n + g + \delta)h = 0. Solving for the steady-state level of k and h yields: :k^* = \left( \frac \right)^ :h^* = \left( \frac \right)^ In the steady state, y^ = (k^)^\alpha (h^)^\beta.


Econometric estimates

Klenow and Rodriguez-Clare cast doubt on the validity of the augmented model because Mankiw, Romer, and Weil's estimates of did not seem consistent with accepted estimates of the effect of increases in schooling on workers' salaries. Though the estimated model explained 78% of variation in income across countries, the estimates of implied that human capital's external effects on national income are greater than its direct effect on workers' salaries.


Accounting for external effects

Theodore Breton provided an insight that reconciled the large effect of human capital from schooling in the Mankiw, Romer and Weil model with the smaller effect of schooling on workers' salaries. He demonstrated that the mathematical properties of the model include significant external effects between the factors of production, because human capital and physical capital are multiplicative factors of production. The external effect of human capital on the productivity of physical capital is evident in the marginal product of physical capital: :MPK=\frac= \frac He showed that the large estimates of the effect of human capital in cross-country estimates of the model are consistent with the smaller effect typically found on workers' salaries when the external effects of human capital on physical capital and labor are taken into account. This insight significantly strengthens the case for the Mankiw, Romer, and Weil version of the Solow–Swan model. Most analyses criticizing this model fail to account for the pecuniary external effects of both types of capital inherent in the model.


Total factor productivity

The exogenous rate of TFP (
total factor productivity In economics, total-factor productivity (TFP), also called multi-factor productivity, is usually measured as the ratio of aggregate output (e.g., GDP) to aggregate inputs. Under some simplifying assumptions about the production technology, grow ...
) growth in the Solow–Swan model is the residual after accounting for capital accumulation. The Mankiw, Romer, and Weil model provide a lower estimate of the TFP (residual) than the basic Solow–Swan model because the addition of human capital to the model enables capital accumulation to explain more of the variation in income across countries. In the basic model, the TFP residual includes the effect of human capital because human capital is not included as a factor of production.


Conditional convergence

The Solow–Swan model augmented with human capital predicts that the income levels of poor countries will tend to
catch up ''Catch Up'' was a children's television series which aired on CBC Television in Canada during the 1978–1979 season. Although the series did not continue past its first year, its hosts would proceed to careers of international scope: * Margot ...
with or converge towards the income levels of rich countries if the poor countries have similar savings rates for both physical capital and human capital as a share of output, a process known as conditional convergence. However, savings rates vary widely across countries. In particular, since considerable financing constraints exist for investment in schooling, savings rates for human capital are likely to vary as a function of cultural and ideological characteristics in each country. Since the 1950s, output/worker in rich and poor countries generally has not converged, but those poor countries that have greatly raised their savings rates have experienced the income convergence predicted by the Solow–Swan model. As an example, output/worker in
Japan Japan ( ja, 日本, or , and formally , ''Nihonkoku'') is an island country in East Asia. It is situated in the northwest Pacific Ocean, and is bordered on the west by the Sea of Japan, while extending from the Sea of Okhotsk in the n ...
, a country which was once relatively poor, has converged to the level of the rich countries. Japan experienced high growth rates after it raised its savings rates in the 1950s and 1960s, and it has experienced slowing growth of output/worker since its savings rates stabilized around 1970, as predicted by the model. The per-capita income levels of the southern states of the United States have tended to converge to the levels in the Northern states. The observed convergence in these states is also consistent with the conditional convergence concept. Whether absolute convergence between countries or regions occurs depends on whether they have similar characteristics, such as: *
Education Education is a purposeful activity directed at achieving certain aims, such as transmitting knowledge or fostering skills and character traits. These aims may include the development of understanding, rationality, kindness, and honesty ...
policy * Institutional arrangements *
Free market In economics, a free market is an economic system in which the prices of goods and services are determined by supply and demand expressed by sellers and buyers. Such markets, as modeled, operate without the intervention of government or any ot ...
s internally, and
trade policy A commercial policy (also referred to as a trade policy or international trade policy) is a government's policy governing international trade. Commercial policy is an all encompassing term that is used to cover topics which involve international ...
with other countries. Additional evidence for conditional convergence comes from multivariate, cross-country regressions.
Econometric Econometrics is the application of statistical methods to economic data in order to give empirical content to economic relationships. M. Hashem Pesaran (1987). "Econometrics," '' The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics'', v. 2, p. 8 p. 8 ...
analysis on Singapore and the other "
East Asian Tigers The Four Asian Tigers (also known as the Four Asian Dragons or Four Little Dragons in Chinese and Korean) are the developed East Asian economies of Hong Kong, Singapore, South Korea, and Taiwan. Between the early 1960s and 1990s, they underwent r ...
" has produced the surprising result that although output per worker has been rising, almost none of their rapid growth had been due to rising per-capita productivity (they have a low "
Solow residual The Solow residual is a number describing empirical productivity growth in an economy from year to year and decade to decade. Robert Solow, the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences-winning economist, defined rising productivity as rising outpu ...
").


See also

*
Economic growth Economic growth can be defined as the increase or improvement in the inflation-adjusted market value of the goods and services produced by an economy in a financial year. Statisticians conventionally measure such growth as the percent rate o ...
*
Endogenous growth theory Endogenous growth theory holds that economic growth is primarily the result of endogenous and not external forces. Endogenous growth theory holds that investment in human capital, innovation, and knowledge are significant contributors to economi ...


Notes


References


Further reading

* * * * * * * * * * van Rijckeghem Willy (1963) : The Structure of Some Macro-Economic Growth Models : a Comparison. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv volume 91 pp. 84–100


External links


Solow Model Videos - 20+ videos walking through derivation of the Solow Growth Model's Conclusions

Video explanation
by Marginal Revolution University
Java applet where you can experiment with parameters and learn about Solow model

Solow Growth Model
by Fiona Maclachlan,
The Wolfram Demonstrations Project The Wolfram Demonstrations Project is an organized, open-source collection of small (or medium-size) interactive programs called Demonstrations, which are meant to visually and interactively represent ideas from a range of fields. It is hos ...
.
A step-by-step explanation of how to understand the Solow Model

Professor José-Víctor Ríos-Rull's course at University of Minnesota
{{DEFAULTSORT:Solow-Swan model Economic growth Economics models