Stromquist Moving-knives Procedure
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

The Stromquist moving-knives procedure is a procedure for
envy-free cake-cutting An envy-free cake-cutting is a kind of fair cake-cutting. It is a division of a heterogeneous resource ("cake") that satisfies the envy-free criterion, namely, that every partner feels that their allocated share is at least as good as any other sha ...
among three players. It is named after
Walter Stromquist Walter may refer to: People * Walter (name), both a surname and a given name * Little Walter, American blues harmonica player Marion Walter Jacobs (1930–1968) * Gunther (wrestler), Austrian professional wrestler and trainer Walter Hahn (born 1 ...
who presented it in 1980. This procedure was the first envy-free moving knife procedure devised for three players. It requires four knives but only two cuts, so each player receives a single connected piece. There is no natural generalization to more than three players which divides the cake without extra cuts. The resulting partition is not necessarily efficient.


Procedure

A
referee A referee is an official, in a variety of sports and competition, responsible for enforcing the rules of the sport, including sportsmanship decisions such as ejection. The official tasked with this job may be known by a variety of other titl ...
moves a sword from left to right over the cake, hypothetically dividing it into small left piece and a large right piece. Each player moves a knife over the right piece, always keeping it parallel to the sword. The players must move their knives in a continuous manner, without making any "jumps".The importance of this continuity is explained here: When any player shouts "cut", the cake is cut by the sword and by whichever of the players' knives happens to be the central one of the three (that is, the second in order from the sword). Then the cake is divided in the following way: * The piece to the left of the sword, which we denote Left, is given to the player who first shouted "cut". We call this player the "shouter" and the other two players the "quieters". * The piece between the sword and the central knife, which we denote Middle, is given to the remaining player whose knife is closest to the sword. * The remaining piece, Right, is given to the third player.


Strategy

Each player can act in a way that guarantees that—according to their own measure—no other player receives more than them: * Always hold your knife such that it divides the part to the right of the sword to two pieces that are equal in your eyes (hence, your knife initially divides the entire cake to two equal parts and then moves rightwards as the sword moves rightwards). * Shout 'cut' when Left becomes equal to the piece you are about to receive if you remain quiet (i.e. if your knife is leftmost, shout 'cut' if Left=Middle; if your knife is rightmost, shout if Left=Right; if your knife is central, shout 'cut' if Left=Middle=Right).


Analysis

We now prove that any player using the above strategy receives an envy-free share. First, consider the two quieters. Each of them receives a piece that contains their own knife, so they do not envy each other. Additionally, because they remained quiet, the piece they receive is larger in their eyes than Left, so they also don't envy the shouter. The shouter receives Left, which is equal to the piece they could receive by remaining silent and larger than the third piece, hence the shouter does not envy any of the quieters. Following this strategy each person gets the largest or one of the largest pieces by their own valuation and therefore the division is envy-free. The same analysis shows that the division is envy-free even in the somewhat degenerate case when there are two shouters, and the leftmost piece is given to any of them.


Dividing a 'bad' cake

The moving-knives procedure can be adapted for
chore division Chore division is a fair division problem in which the divided resource is undesirable, so that each participant wants to get as little as possible. It is the mirror-image of the fair cake-cutting problem, in which the divided resource is desirable ...
- dividing a cake with a negative value.


See also

* The
Fair pie-cutting The fair pie-cutting problem is a variation of the fair cake-cutting problem, in which the resource to be divided is circular. As an example, consider a birthday cake shaped as a disk. The cake should be divided among several children such that no ...
procedure provides a simpler solution to the same problem, using only 3 rotating knives, when the cake is a 1-dimensional circle ("pie"), * The
Robertson–Webb rotating-knife procedure The Robertson–Webb rotating-knife procedure is a procedure for envy-free cake-cutting of a two-dimensional cake among three partners. It makes only two cuts, so each partner receives a single connected piece. Its main advantage over the earlier S ...
provides an even simpler solution, using only 1 rotating knife, when the cake is 2-dimensional. *
Moving-knife procedure In the mathematics of social science, and especially game theory, a moving-knife procedure is a type of solution to the fair division problem. The canonical example is the division of a cake using a knife. The simplest example is a moving-knif ...


References

{{Reflist Fair division protocols Cake-cutting