Social Rationality
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

In behavioural sciences, social rationality is a type of
decision strategy Decision theory (or the theory of choice; not to be confused with Rational choice theory, choice theory) is a branch of applied probability theory concerned with the theory of making decisions based on assigning probabilities to various factors an ...
used in social contexts, in which a set of simple rules is applied in complex and uncertain situations.


Definition

Social rationality is a form of
bounded rationality Bounded rationality is the idea that rationality is limited when individuals make decisions, and under these limitations, rational individuals will select a decision that is satisfactory rather than optimal. Limitations include the difficulty of ...
applied to social contexts, where individuals make choices and predictions under uncertainty.Hertwig, Hoffrage, & the ABC Research Group, 2012 While
game theory Game theory is the study of mathematical models of strategic interactions among rational agents. Myerson, Roger B. (1991). ''Game Theory: Analysis of Conflict,'' Harvard University Press, p.&nbs1 Chapter-preview links, ppvii–xi It has appli ...
deals with well-defined situations, social rationality explicitly deals with situations in which not all alternatives, consequences, and event probabilities can be foreseen. The idea is that, similar to non-social environments, individuals rely, and should rely, on ''fast and frugal heuristics'' in order to deal with complex and genuinely uncertain social environments. This emphasis on simple rules in an uncertain world contrasts with the view that the complexity of social situations requires highly sophisticated mental strategies, as has been assumed in primate researchHumphrey, 1988 and neuroscience,Seymour & Dolan, 2008 among others.


A descriptive and normative program

Social rationality is both a descriptive program and a normative program. The ''descriptive'' program studies the repertoire of heuristics an individual or organization uses, that is, their ''adaptive toolbox''. The ''normative'' program studies the environmental conditions to which a heuristic is adapted, that is, where it performs better than other decision strategies. This approach is called the study of the ecological rationality of social heuristics. It assumes that social heuristics are ''domain- and problem-specific''.Hertwig & Herzog, 2009Gigerenzer, Todd, & the ABC Research Group, 1999


Applications

Heuristics can be applied to social and non-social decision tasks (also called social games and games against nature), judgments, or categorizations. They can use social or non-social input. Social rationality is thus about three of the four possible combinations, excluding the case of heuristics using non-social input for non-social tasks. 'Games against nature' comprise situations where individuals face environmental uncertainty, and need to predict or outwit nature, e.g., harvest food or master hard-to-predict or unpredictable hazards.Hertwig & Hoffrage, 2012 'Social games' include situations, where the decision outcome depends on the choices of others, e.g., in cooperation, competition, mate search and even in morally significant situations.Gigerenzer, 2010 Social rationality has been studied in a number of other fields than human decision-making, e.g. in evolutionary social learning,Morgan, Rendell, Ehn, Hoppitt, & Laland 2012 and social learning in animals.Rieucau & Giraldeau, 2011


Examples


Imitate-the-majority heuristic

An example for a heuristic that is not necessarily social but that requires social input is the ''imitate-the-majority heuristic'', where in a situation of uncertainty, individuals follow the actions or choices of the majority of their peers regardless of their social status. The domain of pro-environmental behavior provides numerous illustrations for this strategy, such as littering behavior in public places,Cialdini, Reno, & Kallgren 1991 the reuse of towels in hotel rooms,Goldstein, Cialdini, & Griskevicius 2008 ull citation needed/ref> and changes in private energy consumption in response to information about the consumption of the majority of neighbors.Schultz, Nolan, Cialdini, Goldstein, & Griskevicius 2007


1/N (Equality heuristic)

Following the ''
equality heuristic Equality may refer to: Society * Political equality, in which all members of a society are of equal standing ** Consociationalism, in which an ethnically, religiously, or linguistically divided state functions by cooperation of each group's elit ...
'' (sometimes called ''1/N rule'') people divide and invest their resources equally in a number of N different options. These options can be both social (e.g., time spent with children) and nonsocial entities (e.g., financial investments or natural resources). For example, many parents invest their limited resources, such as affection, time, and money (e.g., for education) equally into their offspring.Hertwig et al., 2002 ull citation needed/ref> In highly uncertain environments with large numbers of assets and only few possibilities to learn, the equality heuristic can outperform optimizing strategies and yield better performance on various measures of success than optimal asset allocation strategies.DeMiguel, Garlappi, and Uppal (2009)


Social heuristics

Adapted from Hertwig & Herzog, 2009. * Imitate-the-majority heuristic *
Social circle In the social sciences, a social group can be defined as two or more people who interact with one another, share similar characteristics, and collectively have a sense of unity. Regardless, social groups come in a myriad of sizes and varietie ...
heuristic * Averaging heuristic * Tit-for-tat * Generous tit-for-tat (or tit-for-two-tat) * Status tree * Regret matching heuristic * Mirror heuristic * 1/N (Equality heuristic) * Group recognition heuristic * White coat heuristic/ Trust your doctor heuristic * Imitate-the-successful heuristic * Plurality vote-based lexicographic heuristic


See also

*
Social heuristics Social heuristics are simple decision making strategies that guide people's behavior and decisions in the social environment when time, information, or cognitive resources are scarce. Social environments tend to be characterised by complexity an ...
* Ecological rationality * Optimization * Risk * Uncertainty *
Max Planck Institute for Human Development The Max-Planck-Institute for Human Development (Max-Planck-Institut für Bildungsforschung) is an internationally renowned social science research organization. Located in Berlin, it was initiated in 1961 and officially began operations in 1963 ...


Notes


References

*Cialdini, R. B., Reno, R. R., & Kallgren, C. A. (1990). A focus theory of normative conduct: Recycling the concept of norms to reduce littering in public places. ''Journal of Personality and Social Psychology'', 58(6), 1015–1026. *DeMiguel, V., Garlappi, L., & Uppal, R. (2009). Optimal versus naive diversification: How inefficient ist the 1/N portfolio strategy? ''The Review of Financial Studies'', 22(5), 1915-1953. *Gigerenzer, G. (2010). Moral satisficing: Rethinking moral behavior as bounded rationality. ''Topics in Cognitive Science'', 2(3), 528–554. doi:10.1111/j.1756-8765.2010.01094.x *Gigerenzer, G., Todd, P., & the ABC Research Group (1999). ''Simple heuristics that make us smart''. New York: Oxford University Press. *Hertwig, R., & Herzog, S. M. (2009). Fast and frugal heuristics: tools of social rationality. ''Social Cognition'', 27(5), 661–698. Retrieved from http://guilfordjournals.com/doi/abs/10.1521/soco.2009.27.5.661 *Hertwig, R. Hoffrage, U. & the ABC Research Group (2012). ''Simple heuristics in a social world''. New York: Oxford University Press. * * {{cite journal , last1=Morgan , first1=T. J. H. , last2=Rendell , first2=L. E. , last3=Ehn , first3=M. , last4=Hoppitt , first4=W. , last5=Laland , first5=K. N. , title=The evolutionary basis of human social learning , journal=Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences , publisher=The Royal Society , volume=279 , issue=1729 , date=2011-07-27 , issn=0962-8452 , doi=10.1098/rspb.2011.1172 , pages=653–662 , pmid=21795267, pmc= 3248730 *Rieucau, G., & Giraldeau, L.-A. (2011). Exploring the costs and benefits of social information use: An appraisal of current experimental evidence. ''Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B'', 366(1567), 949–957. doi:10.1098/rstb.2010.0325 *Seymour, B., & Dolan, R. (2008). Emotion, decision making, and the amygdala. ''Neuron'', 58, 662–671. *Schultz, P. W., Nolan, J. M., Cialdini, R. B., Goldstein, N. J., & Griskevicius, V. (2007). The constructive, destructive, and reconstructive power of social norms. ''Psychological Science'', 18(5), 429–434. *Simon, Herbert A. (1956). Rational choice and the structure of the environment. ''Psychological Review'', 63(2), 129–138. Behavioral economics Game theory Rational choice theory