HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

''Principles of Political Economy Considered with a View to their Applications'', simply referred to as ''Principles of Political Economy'', was written by the nineteenth-century British political economist
Thomas Malthus Thomas Robert Malthus (; 13/14 February 1766 – 29 December 1834) was an English cleric, scholar and influential economist in the fields of political economy and demography. In his 1798 book ''An Essay on the Principle of Population'', Mal ...
in 1820. Malthus wrote ''Principles of Political Economy'' as a rebuttal to
David Ricardo David Ricardo (18 April 1772 – 11 September 1823) was a British political economist. He was one of the most influential of the classical economists along with Thomas Malthus, Adam Smith and James Mill. Ricardo was also a politician, and a ...
's ''
On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation '' the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation'' (19 April 1817) is a book by David Ricardo on economics. The book concludes that land rent grows as population increases. It also presents the theory of comparative advantage, the theory tha ...
''. While the main focus of their work is to explain economic depressions in Europe and the reasons why they occur, Malthus uses his scholarship to explore price determination and the value of goods.


Summary of ''Principles of Political Economy''

In ''Principles of Political Economy'', Malthus' rebuts David Ricardo's work, particularly rejecting idea developed by
Jean Baptiste Say Jean-Baptiste Say (; 5 January 1767 – 15 November 1832) was a liberal French economist and businessman who argued in favor of competition, free trade and lifting restraints on business. He is best known for Say's law—also known as the law of ...
that theorizes that supply generates its own demand, known as Say's Law.
Say's Law In classical economics, Say's law, or the law of markets, is the claim that the production of a product creates demand for another product by providing something of value which can be exchanged for that other product. So, production is the source ...
emphasizes the idea that there is no tendency towards a depression because as supply increases, people will naturally demand more. Say believes that an overflow of supply of certain goods will trigger a lack of supply of another type of good. This will create a new balance in the economy. Malthus claims that supply does not generate its own demand and that oversupply can lead the economy to recession. Malthus understands production and demand to exist independent of each other. Both are determined by their own factors. From this Malthus generates the idea of "
effective demand In economics, effective demand (ED) in a market is the demand for a product or service which occurs when purchasers are constrained in a different market. It contrasts with notional demand, which is the demand that occurs when purchasers are not ...
," which later becomes popular in
Keynesian economics Keynesian economics ( ; sometimes Keynesianism, named after British economist John Maynard Keynes) are the various macroeconomic theories and models of how aggregate demand (total spending in the economy) strongly influences economic output ...
. "Effective demand" iterates that consumers purchase more or less of a good depending on the price a firm charges for it. Malthus' idea suggests that the amount of goods supplied may be a result of the demand. Furthermore, Malthus argues that the economy tends to move towards recessions because productivity often grows more quickly than demand. Malthus suggests increasing government spending and private investment on luxuries to cure recessions. This idea firmly goes against the notion that Ricardo and Say hold that the economy will fix itself through demand.


Second edition

A second edition of Malthus' ''Principles of Political Economy'' was published in 1836. After the first version's publication, Adam Smith develops the idea that an object's inherent value is related to the labor that went into its creation. Additionally, Smith creates the notion that a good's price also moves in the direction of the price of other commodities. After careful contemplation, Malthus adopts Smith's theory of value. This new thought process goes against his previous belief that there is no accurate way to measure an object's value. Although this new conclusion would only call for revision of the sixth and seventh sections of his second chapter, Malthus uses this new revelation as an excuse to re-examine his whole book. For the most part, his additions simply clarify sections and omit ideas more clear in other sections. He does not alter any of his main ideas in his book. Malthus died before he was able to publish the new edition, but it is believed he made all his intended alterations. His work was later collected and published in 1836.


Responses and critiques of his work

Malthus' book received mixed feedback from other economists of the time. Twentieth century British economist
John Maynard Keynes John Maynard Keynes, 1st Baron Keynes, ( ; 5 June 1883 – 21 April 1946), was an English economist whose ideas fundamentally changed the theory and practice of macroeconomics and the economic policies of governments. Originally trained in ...
is considered an admirer of Malthus' work. In fact, he is even quoted in saying, “If only Malthus, instead of Ricardo, had been the parent stem from which nineteenth-century economics proceeded, what a much wiser and richer place the world would be today!” Many of Keynes' ideas that became the basis of Keynesian economics are influenced by ''Principles of Political Economy.'' Although Malthus fails to connect long-run supply and demand curve as setting the natural price of an item, Malthus is one of the first to describe the natural price of an item. Keynes utilizes this idea and also draws on Malthus' concept of government spending during times of economic crisis. Keynes cites this chapter of Malthus' book as "a masterly exposition of the conditions which determine the optimum of saving in the actual economic system in which we live." However, Keynes also critiques Thomas Malthus. He faults Malthus' work for being "unable to explain clearly (apart from an appeal to the facts of common observation) how and why effective demand could be deficient or excessive."
John Stuart Mill John Stuart Mill (20 May 1806 – 7 May 1873) was an English philosopher, political economist, Member of Parliament (MP) and civil servant. One of the most influential thinkers in the history of classical liberalism, he contributed widely to ...
, a nineteenth-century British economist, also criticizes Malthus' ''Principles of Political Economy''. He calls Malthus' work "a more mischievous doctrine," and mocks Malthus for believing that government intervention is an appropriate solution to recessions. Mill takes the approach that the government is too corrupt and that a moral individual would not accept its help. Furthermore, he emphasizes that Say's Law is accurate and justified in economic studies.
William Blake William Blake (28 November 1757 – 12 August 1827) was an English poet, painter, and printmaker. Largely unrecognised during his life, Blake is now considered a seminal figure in the history of the Romantic poetry, poetry and visual art of t ...
, another economist of the time, takes the opposite opinion of Mill. Blake applauds Malthus' idea of government expenditure in order to stimulate the economy. Without Malthus' suggested government intervention, Blake believes the economy would remain stuck in a depression.


Impact

Malthus' work did not spark many economic debates at the time of its publication. In fact, many denied Malthus' ideas on recessions. Say's Law remained the more commonly accepted theory at the time due to its popularity. Malthus' book does not attract much attention until the Great Depression occurs and it becomes evident that depressions are real. After this, economists such as John Maynard Keynes begin to look more deeply into Malthus' ideas and utilize them in their own work.


See also

* '' Principles of Political Economy''


References

{{Authority control 1820 non-fiction books Classical economics books Political economy