Physical Transmission Right
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

Electricity transmission congestion is a condition of the
electrical grid An electrical grid is an interconnected network for electricity delivery from producers to consumers. Electrical grids vary in size and can cover whole countries or continents. It consists of:Kaplan, S. M. (2009). Smart Grid. Electrical Power ...
that prevents the accepted or forecasted
load schedule Load or LOAD may refer to: Aeronautics and transportation * Load factor (aeronautics), the ratio of the lift of an aircraft to its weight *Passenger load factor, the ratio of revenue passenger miles to available seat miles of a particular transp ...
s from being implemented due to the grid configuration and equipment performance limitations. In simple terms, congestion occurs when overloaded transmission lines are unable to carry additional electricity flow due to the risk of overheating and the transmission system operator (TSO) has to direct the providers to adjust their dispatch levels to accommodate the constraint or in an electricity market a power plant can produce electricity at a competitive price but cannot transmit the power to a willing buyer. Congestion increases the electricity prices for some customers.


Definitions

There is no universally accepted definition of the transmission congestion. Congestion is not an event, so it is frequently not possible to pinpoint its place and time (in this respect it is similar to
traffic congestion Traffic congestion is a condition in transport that is characterized by slower speeds, longer trip times, and increased vehicular queueing. Traffic congestion on urban road networks has increased substantially since the 1950s. When traffic de ...
). Regulators define congestion as a condition that prevents market transactions from being completed, while a transmission system operator sees it as inability to maintain the security of the power system operation with the
power flow In power engineering, the power-flow study, or load-flow study, is a numerical analysis of the flow of electric power in an interconnected system. A power-flow study usually uses simplified notations such as a one-line diagram and per-unit system ...
scheduled for the grid. A congestion is a symptom of a constraint or a combination of constraints in a transmission system, usually the limits on physical electricity flow are used to prevent the overheating, unacceptable voltage levels, and loss of system stability. Congestion can be permanent, an effect of the system configuration, or temporary, due to a fault in the transmission equipment.


Congestion management

Avoiding the congestion is essential for a competitive electricity market and is "one of the toughest problems" of its design. The goal is ensure that a power flow as defined by the wholesale market result does not violate the constraints during the normal operation of the grid and in the case of failure of any one particular component (so called ''n-1 criterion''). The existing markets use a range of approaches to solve the problem. On one end of this range is "uniform pricing" that ignores the transmission constraints altogether and lets the market find a single price for all the locations ("nodes"). On the other end "
locational marginal pricing In a broad sense, an electricity market is a system that facilitates the exchange of electricity-related goods and services. During more than a century of evolution of the electric power industry, the economics of the electricity markets had un ...
" accommodates all the constraints by defining a separate pricing for each node (thus another name, "nodal pricing"). The uniform pricing has an advantage of transparent market design and quick clearing, so auctions can happen frequently, typically they start a day ahead of the delivery ("day-ahead" auction) and continue until the delivery (so called "intra-day" auctions). However, the market result might violate the congestion constraints and thus cannot be implemented at the time of delivery (in "real-time"). If this is the case, the TSO intervenes and uses so called system redispatch by changing the schedules of the generators in a way that the load can be served. With nodal pricing all grid constraints are accounted for during the clearing and different prices are set for different nodes, this typically requires the independent system operator (ISO) to manage the market clearing. The drawback of the nodal pricing is that the local markets might not have enough participants to efficiently function. In particular, in the
load pocket A load pocket is an area of electric grid (typically small) that has limited ability to import electricity due to either very high concentration of demand or insufficient transmission capabilities ("intra-zonal congestion") and therefore cannot be e ...
s (areas of the grid with concentrated load and lack of tie lines to the rest of the system) a large generator might exhibit significant market power, forcing the price for this node to be directly regulated on a cost basis. The zonal pricing represents a compromise where the grid is split into relatively large zones, electricity price within each zone is uniform (and thus intra-zone congestion need to be resolved with a redispatch), but the inter-zone constraints are accounted for during the market clearing via different prices for different zones.


Transmission rights

To avoid congestion, it might be necessary to deny some transmission transactions. One way to do it is through the transmission rights. The owner of a transmission right is entitled to transport a predefined amount of electric power from a source location on the network to the destination. There are two types of transmission rights: * physical transmission right (PTR) provides a property right to a portion of a capacity of a transmission line, which is reserved for the holder's exclusive use (the holder can deny access to the transmission capacity to non-holders. ). The right can be acquired by building a transmission line or by purchasing the right form some other holder, so costs are typically known in advance. The owner can "sublet" the capacity to supplement the return on investment (for example, at a time when the capacity is not being used). The PTRs are essentially self-scheduling and in practice not only can interfere with the ability of a system operator to perform the economic dispatch, but are incompatible with
locational marginal pricing In a broad sense, an electricity market is a system that facilitates the exchange of electricity-related goods and services. During more than a century of evolution of the electric power industry, the economics of the electricity markets had un ...
, as the holder of a right from, say, A to B, can artificially increase prices in B (an lower in A) by simply withholding the access; * financial transmission right (FTR) is similar to PTR in appearance (it specifies the source, destination, and power in MW), but does not reserve the line yet instead provides its holder with a payout that is equal to the difference in the price of electricity between the source and the destination (form of a congestion rent). The funds for the payment are collected whenever the electricity is purchased in the lower-cost location and resold in a higher-cost one, so the FTRs cannot be used in a uniform pricing market arrangement.


Example of an FTR operation

In a simple example of FTR operation, locations A and B are connected with a 1000 MW line. Location A has a load of 200 MW and two generation companies: * GA1 with 1000 MW capacity and marginal cost of $10/MW; * GA2 with 1000 MW capacity and marginal cost of $15/MW. Location B has a load of 2500 MW and a single generator GB with 2000 MW capacity and marginal cost of $30/MW. The electricity market with locational pricing will fully engage the 1000 MW line and settle on: * $15 at location A, as GA1 cannot satisfy all demand (transmission line plus local load) and the price will be thus determined by GA2; * $30 at B: the transmission line cannot satisfy all local load and the price is thus determined by GB. GA1, standing to gain most if the links between A and B are improved, decides to build another 1000-MW transmission line. Now there is no congestion, and the market will settle at the same price in both A and B ($30, since GA1 and GA2 cannot satisfy all demand, and the price will be determined by the cost of GB). GA1 will hold the FTR for 1000 MW, but will not collect anything from this right, instead pocketing the difference between its $10 cost and $30 price. A new plant, GA3, is constructed in A with capacity of 1000 MW and marginal cost of $9/MW. Now the pricing in A is $15 again (determined by GA2), pricing at B is still $30. Although the line built by GA1 might now be effectively used by GA3, GA1 as a holder of FTR receives the congestion rent for electricity transmitted over the line that GA1 had invested into. The arrangement works as if GA1 had leased the line to GA3 for the full value of the line, so FTRs are similar to tradable securities, but with automated trading.


References


Sources

* * * * {{cite journal , last1 = Lyons , first1 = Karen , last2 = Fraser , first2 = Hamish , last3 = Parmesano , first3 = Hethie , title = An Introduction to Financial Transmission Rights , journal = The Electricity Journal , date = December 2000 , volume = 13 , issue = 10 , pages = 31–37 , issn = 1040-6190 , doi = 10.1016/S1040-6190(00)00164-0 , pmid = , url = https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S1040619000001640 Electric power transmission Electrical engineering