In
economics
Economics () is a behavioral science that studies the Production (economics), production, distribution (economics), distribution, and Consumption (economics), consumption of goods and services.
Economics focuses on the behaviour and interac ...
the generalized-Ozaki (GO) cost function is a general description of the
cost
Cost is the value of money that has been used up to produce something or deliver a service, and hence is not available for use anymore. In business, the cost may be one of acquisition, in which case the amount of money expended to acquire it i ...
of production proposed by Shinichiro Nakamura.
The GO cost function is notable for explicitly considering nonhomothetic technology, where the proportions of inputs can vary as the output changes. This stands in contrast to the standard production model, which assumes homothetic technology.
The GO function
For a given output
, at time
and a vector of
input prices
, the generalized-Ozaki (GO) cost function
is expressed as
Here,
and
,
. By applying the
Shephard's lemma
Shephard's lemma is a result in microeconomics having applications in the theory of the firm and in consumer choice. The lemma states that if indifference curves of the expenditure or cost function are convex, then the cost-minimizing point of a ...
, we derive the demand function for input
,
:
The GO cost function is flexible in the price space, and treats scale effects and technical change in a highly general manner.
The concavity condition which ensures that a constant function aligns with cost minimization for a specific set of
, necessitates that its Hessian (the matrix of second partial derivatives with respect to
and
) being negative semidefinite.
Several notable special cases can be identified:
* Homothticity (HT):
for all
. All input levels (
) scale proportionally with the overall output level (
).
* Homogeneity of (of degree one) in output (HG):
in addition to HT.
* Factor limitationality (FL):
for all
. None of the input levels (
) depend on
.
* Neutral technical change (NT):
for all
.
When (HT) holds, the GO function reduces to the Generalized Leontief function of Diewert,
[Diewert, W. Erwin. "An application of the Shephard duality theorem: A generalized Leontief production function." ''Journal of political economy'' 79.3 (1971): 481-507.] A well-known flexible functional form for cost and production functions. When (FL) hods, it reduces to a non-linear version of Leontief's model, which explains the cross-sectional variation of
when variations in input prices were negligible:
Background
Cost- and production functions
In economics, production technology is typically represented by the production function
, which, in the case of a single output
and
inputs, is written as
. When considering cost minimization for a given set of prices
and
, the corresponding cost function
can be expressed as:
The duality theorems of cost and production functions state that once a well-behaved cost function is established, one can derive the corresponding production function, and vice versa.
For a given cost function
, the corresponding production function
can be obtained as
[Charles Blackorby, Daniel Primont, R. Robert Russell , title=Duality, Separability, and Functional Structure: Theory and Economic Applications, Elsevier Science Ltd, 1978, ] (a more rigorous derivation involves using a distance function instead of a production function
) :
In essence, under general conditions, a specific technology can be equally effectively represented by both cost and production functions.
One advantage of using a cost function rather than a production function is that the demand functions for inputs can be easily derived from the former using
Shephard's lemma
Shephard's lemma is a result in microeconomics having applications in the theory of the firm and in consumer choice. The lemma states that if indifference curves of the expenditure or cost function are convex, then the cost-minimizing point of a ...
, whereas this process can become cumbersome with the production function.
Homothetic- and Nonhomothetic Technology
Commonly used forms of production functions, such as
Cobb-Douglas and
Constant Elasticity of Substitution
Constant elasticity of substitution (CES) is a common specification of many production functions and utility function
In economics, utility is a measure of a certain person's satisfaction from a certain state of the world. Over time, the term ...
(CES) functions exhibit homothticity.
This property means that the production function
can be represented as a positive monotone transformation of a linear-homogeneous function
:
where
for any
.
The
Cobb-Douglas function is a special case of the
CES function for which the elasticity of substitution between the inputs,
, is one.
For a homothetic technology, the cost function can be represented as
where
is a monotone increasing function, and
is termed a unit cost function. From Shephard's lemma, we obtain the following expression for the ratio of inputs
and
:
,
which implies that for a homothetic technology, the ratio of inputs depends solely on prices and not on the scale of output.
However, empirical studies on the cross-section of establishments show that the FL model () effectively explains the data, particularly for heavy industries such as steel mills, paper mills, basic chemical sectors, and power stations, indicating that homotheticity may not be applicable.
Furthermore, in the areas of trade, homothetic and monolithic functional models do not accurately predict results. One example is in the gravity equation for trade, or how much will two countries trade with each other based on GDP and distance. This led researchers to explore non-homothetic models of production, to fit with a
cross section analysis of producer behavior, for example, when producers would begin to minimize costs by switching inputs or investing in increased production.
Flexible Functional Forms
CES functions (note that
Cobb-Douglas is a special case of CES) typically involve only two inputs, such as capital and labor.
While they can be extended to include more than two inputs, assuming the same degree of substitutability for all inputs may seem overly restrictive (refer to
CES for further details on this topic, including the potential for accommodating diverse elasticities of substitution among inputs, although this capability is somewhat constrained).
To address this limitation, flexible functional forms have been developed.
These general functional forms are called flexible functional forms (FFFs) because they do not impose any restrictions a priori on the degree of substitutability among inputs. These FFFs can provide a second-order approximation to any twice-differentiable function that meets the necessary regulatory conditions, including basic technological conditions and those consistent with cost minimization.
Widely used examples of FFFs are the
transcendental logarithmic (translog) function and the Generalized Leontief (GL) function.
The translog function extends the Cobb-Douglas function to the second order, while the GL function performs a similar extension to the Leontief production function.
Limitations
A drawback of the GL function is its inability to be globally concave without sacrificing flexibility in the price space.
This limitation also applies to the GO function, as it is a non-homothetic extension of the GL.
In a subsequent study, Nakamura attempted to address this issue by employing the Generalized McFadden function.
For further advancements in this area, refer to Ryan and Wales.
Moreover, both the GO function and the underlying GL function presume immediate adjustments of inputs in response to changes in
and
.
This oversimplifies the reality where technological changes entail significant investments in plant and equipment, thus requiring time, often occurring over years rather than instantaneously.
One way to address this issue will be to resort to a variable cost function that explicitly takes into account differences in the speed of adjustments among inputs.
[Morrison, Catherine. "Quasi-fixed inputs in US and Japanese manufacturing: a generalized Leontief restricted cost function approach." ''The Review of Economics and Statistics'' (1988): 275-287.]
Notes
References
See also
Production function
In economics, a production function gives the technological relation between quantities of physical inputs and quantities of output of goods. The production function is one of the key concepts of mainstream economics, mainstream neoclassical econ ...
List of production functions
Constant elasticity of substitution
Constant elasticity of substitution (CES) is a common specification of many production functions and utility function
In economics, utility is a measure of a certain person's satisfaction from a certain state of the world. Over time, the term ...
Shephard's lemma
Shephard's lemma is a result in microeconomics having applications in the theory of the firm and in consumer choice. The lemma states that if indifference curves of the expenditure or cost function are convex, then the cost-minimizing point of a ...
Returns to scale
In economics, the concept of returns to scale arises in the context of a firm's production function. It explains the long-run linkage of increase in output (production) relative to associated increases in the inputs (factors of production).
In th ...
Functions and mappings
Production economics