HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

In
microeconomics Microeconomics is a branch of mainstream economics that studies the behavior of individuals and firms in making decisions regarding the allocation of scarce resources and the interactions among these individuals and firms. Microeconomics fo ...
, the expenditure function gives the minimum amount of money an individual needs to spend to achieve some level of
utility As a topic of economics, utility is used to model worth or value. Its usage has evolved significantly over time. The term was introduced initially as a measure of pleasure or happiness as part of the theory of utilitarianism by moral philosopher ...
, given a
utility function As a topic of economics, utility is used to model worth or value. Its usage has evolved significantly over time. The term was introduced initially as a measure of pleasure or happiness as part of the theory of utilitarianism by moral philosopher ...
and the prices of the available goods. Formally, if there is a utility function u that describes preferences over ''n '' commodities, the expenditure function :e(p, u^*) : \textbf R^n_+ \times \textbf R \rightarrow \textbf R says what amount of money is needed to achieve a utility u^* if the ''n'' prices are given by the price vector p. This function is defined by :e(p, u^*) = \min_ p \cdot x where :\geq(u^*) = \ is the set of all bundles that give utility at least as good as u^*. Expressed equivalently, the individual minimizes expenditure x_1p_1+\dots +x_n p_n subject to the minimal utility constraint that u(x_1, \dots , x_n) \ge u^*, giving optimal quantities to consume of the various goods as x_1^*, \dots x_n^* as function of u^* and the prices; then the expenditure function is :e(p_1, \dots , p_n ; u^*)=p_1 x_1^*+\dots + p_n x_n^*.


Features of Expenditure Functions

:(Properties of the Expenditure Function) Suppose u is a continuous utility function representing a locally non-satiated preference relation º on Rn +. Then e(p, u) is :1.   Homogeneous of degree one in p: for all and \lambda >0, e(\lambda p,u)=\lambda e(p,u); :2.   Continuous in p and u; :3.   Nondecreasing in p and strictly increasing in u provided p \gg 0 ; :4.   Concave in p :5. If the utility function is strictly quasi-concave, there is the
Shephard's lemma Shephard's lemma is a major result in microeconomics having applications in the theory of the firm and in consumer choice. The lemma states that if indifference curves of the expenditure or cost function are convex, then the cost minimizing point ...
Proof (1) As in the above proposition, note that e(\lambda p,u)=\min_ \lambda p\cdot x=\lambda \min_ p\cdot x=\lambda e(p,u) (2) Continue on the domain e: \textbf R_^N*\textbf R\rightarrow \textbf R (3) Let p^\prime>p and suppose x \in h(p^\prime,u). Then u(h)\geq u, and e(p^\prime,u)=p^\prime\cdot x\geq p \cdot x . It follows immediately that e(p,u)\leq e(p^\prime,u). For the second statement , suppose to the contrary that for some u^\prime > u, e(p,u^\prime)\leq e(p,u) Than, for some x \in h(p,u), u(x)=u^\prime>u, which contradicts the "no excess utility" conclusion of the previous proposition (4)Let t \in(0,1) and suppose x \in h(tp+(1-t)p^\prime). Then, p \cdot x\geq e(p,u) and p^\prime \cdot x\geq e(p^\prime,u), so e(tp+(1-t)p^\prime,u)=(tp+(1-t)p^\prime)\cdot x\geqte(p,u)+(1-t)e(p^\prime,u). (5) \frac=x^h_i(p^0,u^0)


Expenditure and indirect utility

The expenditure function is the inverse of the
indirect utility __NOTOC__ In economics, a consumer's indirect utility function v(p, w) gives the consumer's maximal attainable utility when faced with a vector p of goods prices and an amount of income w. It reflects both the consumer's preferences and market co ...
function when the prices are kept constant. I.e, for every price vector p and income level I: :e(p, v(p,I)) \equiv I There is a duality relationship between expenditure function and utility function. If given a specific regular quasi-concave utility function, the corresponding price is homogeneous, and the utility is monotonically increasing expenditure function, conversely, the given price is homogeneous, and the utility is monotonically increasing expenditure function will generate the regular quasi-concave utility function. In addition to the property that prices are once homogeneous and utility is monotonically increasing, the expenditure function usually assumes (1) is a non-negative function, i.e., E(P \cdot u)>O; (2) For P, it is non-decreasing, i.e., E(p^1 u)> E(p^2 u),u> Op^l>p^2> O_N ; (3)E(Pu) is a concave function. That is, e(np^l+(1-n)p^2)u )>\lambda E(p^1u)(1-n)E(p^2u)y>0 O<\lambda<1p^l\geq O_Np^2 \geq O_N Expenditure function is an important theoretical method to study consumer behavior. Expenditure function is very similar to cost function in production theory. Dual to the utility maximization problem is the cost minimization problem


Example

Suppose the utility function is the Cobb-Douglas function u(x_1, x_2) = x_1^x_2^, which generates the demand functions, pp. 111, has the general formula. : x_1(p_1, p_2, I) = \frac \;\;\;\; \;\;\; x_2(p_1, p_2, I) = \frac, where I is the consumer's income. One way to find the expenditure function is to first find the
indirect utility function __NOTOC__ In economics, a consumer's indirect utility function v(p, w) gives the consumer's maximal attainable utility when faced with a vector p of goods prices and an amount of income w. It reflects both the consumer's preferences and market con ...
and then invert it. The indirect utility function v(p_1, p_2, I) is found by replacing the quantities in the utility function with the demand functions thus: : v(p_1, p_2,I) = u(x_1^*, x_2^*) = (x_1^*)^(x_2^*)^ = \left( \frac\right)^ \left( \frac\right)^ = (.6^ * .4^)I^p_1^ p_2^ = K p_1^ p_2^I, where K = (.6^ * .4^). Then since e(p_1, p_2, u) = e(p_1, p_2, v(p_1, p_2, I)) =I when the consumer optimizes, we can invert the indirect utility function to find the expenditure function: : e(p_1, p_2, u) = (1/K) p_1^ p_2^u, Alternatively, the expenditure function can be found by solving the problem of minimizing (p_1x_1+ p_2x_2) subject to the constraint u(x_1, x_2) \geq u^*. This yields conditional demand functions x_1^*(p_1, p_2, u^*) and x_2^*(p_1, p_2, u^*) and the expenditure function is then : e(p_1, p_2, u^*) = p_1x_1^*+ p_2x_2^*


See also

*
Expenditure minimization problem In microeconomics, the expenditure minimization problem is the dual of the utility maximization problem: "how much money do I need to reach a certain level of happiness?". This question comes in two parts. Given a consumer's utility function, pr ...
*
Hicksian demand function In microeconomics, a consumer's Hicksian demand function or compensated demand function for a good is his quantity demanded as part of the solution to minimizing his expenditure on all goods while delivering a fixed level of utility. Essentia ...
*
Slutsky equation The Slutsky equation (or Slutsky identity) in economics, named after Eugen Slutsky, relates changes in Marshallian (uncompensated) demand to changes in Hicksian (compensated) demand, which is known as such since it compensates to maintain a fixed ...
*
Utility maximization problem Utility maximization was first developed by utilitarian philosophers Jeremy Bentham and John Stuart Mill. In microeconomics, the utility maximization problem is the problem consumers face: "How should I spend my money in order to maximize my uti ...
*
Budget constraint In economics, a budget constraint represents all the combinations of goods and services that a consumer may purchase given current prices within his or her given income. Consumer theory uses the concepts of a budget constraint and a preference ...
*
Consumption set The theory of consumer choice is the branch of microeconomics that relates Preference (economics), preferences to consumption expenditures and to supply and demand, consumer demand curves. It analyzes how consumers maximize the desirability of t ...
*
Shephard's lemma Shephard's lemma is a major result in microeconomics having applications in the theory of the firm and in consumer choice. The lemma states that if indifference curves of the expenditure or cost function are convex, then the cost minimizing point ...


References

* * * {{DEFAULTSORT:Expenditure Function Consumer theory Expenditure