Cardinal voting refers to any
electoral system
An electoral system or voting system is a set of rules that determine how elections and referendums are conducted and how their results are determined. Electoral systems are used in politics to elect governments, while non-political elections m ...
which allows the voter to give each candidate an independent evaluation, typically a rating or grade. These are also referred to as "rated" (ratings ballot), "evaluative", "graded", or "absolute" voting systems.
''Cardinal'' methods (based on
cardinal utility) and ''
ordinal methods'' (based on ''
ordinal utility'') are two main categories of modern voting systems, along with
plurality voting
Plurality voting refers to electoral systems in which a candidate, or candidates, who poll more than any other counterpart (that is, receive a plurality (voting), plurality), are elected. In systems based on single-member districts, it elects j ...
.
[
][
]
Variants
There are several voting systems that allow independent ratings of each candidate. For example:
*
Approval voting (AV) is the simplest possible method, which allows only the two grades (0, 1): "approved" or "unapproved".
* Evaluative voting (EV) or
combined approval voting
Combined approval voting (CAV) is an electoral system where each voter may express approval, disapproval, or indifference toward each candidate. The winner is the most-approved candidate.
It is a cardinal system, a variation of score and approva ...
(CAV) uses 3 grades (−1, 0, +1): "against", "abstain", or "for".
*
Score voting or range voting, in which ratings are numerical and the candidate with the highest ''average'' (or total) rating wins.
** Score voting uses a discrete integer scale, typically from 0 to 5 or 0 to 9.
** Range voting uses a continuous scale from 0 to 1.
*
Highest median rules, which elect the candidate with the highest ''median'' grade. The various highest median rules differ in their tie-breaking methods. The
majority judgment, in which the grades are associated to expressions (such as "Excellent", to "Poor"), is the most common example as it is the first such rule that has been studied, but other rules have since been proposed, e.g. the
typical judgment
Highest median voting rules are cardinal voting rules, where the winning candidate is a candidate with the highest median rating. As these employ ratings, each voter rates the different candidates on an ordered, numerical or verbal scale.
The var ...
or the
usual judgment.
*
STAR voting, in which scores are from 0 to 5, and the most-preferred of the top-two highest-scoring candidates wins.
* Majority Approval Voting, a scored variant of
Bucklin voting, typically using letter grades (such as "A" through "F").
* 3-2-1 voting, in which voters rate each candidate "Good", "OK", or "Bad", and there are three automatic elimination steps to tally them: first step selects the three candidates with the most "Good" ratings, second the two with the least "Bad", and out of these the one preferred by the majority wins.
Additionally, several cardinal systems have variants for multi-winner elections, typically meant to produce
proportional representation
Proportional representation (PR) refers to a type of electoral system under which subgroups of an electorate are reflected proportionately in the elected body. The concept applies mainly to geographical (e.g. states, regions) and political divis ...
, such as:
*
Proportional approval voting
*
Sequential proportional approval voting
*
Satisfaction approval voting
* Re-weighted range voting
Relationship to rankings
Ratings ballots can be converted to ranked/preferential ballots. For example:
This requires the voting system to accommodate a voter's indifference between two candidates (as in
Ranked Pairs or
Schulze method).
The opposite is not true: Rankings cannot be converted to ratings, since ratings carry more information about strength of preference, which is destroyed when converting to rankings.
Analysis
By avoiding ranking (and its implication of a monotonic approval reduction from most- to least-preferred candidate) cardinal voting methods may solve a very difficult problem:
A foundational result in
social choice theory
Social choice theory or social choice is a theoretical framework for analysis of combining individual opinions, preferences, interests, or welfares to reach a ''collective decision'' or ''social welfare'' in some sense. Amartya Sen (2008). "So ...
(the study of voting methods) is
Arrow's impossibility theorem
Arrow's impossibility theorem, the general possibility theorem or Arrow's paradox is an impossibility theorem in social choice theory that states that when voters have three or more distinct alternatives (options), no ranked voting electoral syst ...
, which states that no method can comply with all of a simple set of desirable criteria. However, since one of these criteria (called "universality") implicitly requires that a method be ordinal, not cardinal, Arrow's theorem does not apply to cardinal methods.
Others, however, argue that ratings are fundamentally invalid, because meaningful interpersonal comparisons of utility are impossible. This was Arrow's original justification for only considering ranked systems, but later in life he stated that cardinal methods are "probably the best".
Cardinal methods inherently impose a tactical concern that any voter has regarding their second-favorite candidate, in the case that there are 3 or more candidates. Score too high (or Approve) and the voter harms their favorite candidate's chance to win. Score too low (or not Approve) and the voter helps the candidate they least desire to beat their second-favorite and perhaps win.
Psychological research has shown that cardinal
ratings (on a numerical or
Likert scale, for instance) are more valid and convey more information than ordinal rankings in measuring human opinion.
Cardinal methods can, but don't have to satisfy the
Condorcet winner criterion.
Strategic voting
The weighted mean utility theorem gives the optimal strategy for cardinal voting, which is to give maximum score for all options above expected value of the winning option and minimum score for all other options.
[Approval Voting, Steven J. Brams, Peter C. Fishburn, 1983]
See also
*
Borda count
References
{{reflist, 30em
Electoral systems
Psephology
Public choice theory
Social choice theory