Calvo (staggered) Contracts
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

A Calvo contract is the name given in macroeconomics to the pricing model that when a firm sets a
nominal price In economics, nominal value is measured in terms of money, whereas real value is measured against goods or services. A real value is one which has been adjusted for inflation, enabling comparison of quantities as if the prices of goods had not c ...
there is a constant
probability Probability is the branch of mathematics concerning numerical descriptions of how likely an event is to occur, or how likely it is that a proposition is true. The probability of an event is a number between 0 and 1, where, roughly speakin ...
that a firm might be able to reset its price which is independent of the time since the price was last reset. The model was first put forward by
Guillermo Calvo Guillermo Antonio Calvo (born 1941) is an Argentine-American economist who is director of Columbia University's mid-career Program in Economic Policy Management in their School of International and Public Affairs (SIPA). He published significan ...
in his 1983 article "Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework". The original article was written in a
continuous time In mathematical dynamics, discrete time and continuous time are two alternative frameworks within which variables that evolve over time are modeled. Discrete time Discrete time views values of variables as occurring at distinct, separate "po ...
mathematical framework, but nowadays is mostly used in its discrete time version. The Calvo model is the most common way to model
nominal rigidity Nominal rigidity, also known as price-stickiness or wage-stickiness, is a situation in which a nominal price is resistant to change. Complete nominal rigidity occurs when a price is fixed in nominal terms for a relevant period of time. For examp ...
in
new Keynesian New Keynesian economics is a school of macroeconomics that strives to provide microeconomic foundations for Keynesian economics. It developed partly as a response to criticisms of Keynesian macroeconomics by adherents of new classical macroec ...
DSGE macroeconomic models.


The Calvo model of pricing

We can define the probability that the firm can reset its price in any one period as h (the
hazard rate Survival analysis is a branch of statistics for analyzing the expected duration of time until one event occurs, such as death in biological organisms and failure in mechanical systems. This topic is called reliability theory or reliability analys ...
), or equivalently the probability (1-h) that the price will remain unchanged in that period (the survival rate). The probability h is sometimes called the "Calvo probability" in this context. In the Calvo model the crucial feature is that the price-setter does not know how long the nominal price will remain in place. The probability of the current price lasting for exactly i periods more is :\mathrm (1-h)^ h The probability of surviving i subsequent periods thus follows a
geometric distribution In probability theory and statistics, the geometric distribution is either one of two discrete probability distributions: * The probability distribution of the number ''X'' of Bernoulli trials needed to get one success, supported on the set \; * ...
, with the expected duration of the nominal price from when it is first set is E mathrm[i=h^.__For_example,_if_the_Calvo_probability_''h''_is_0.25_per_period,_the_expected_duration_is_4_periods.__Since_the_Calvo_probability_is_constant_and_does_not_depend_on_how_long_it_has_been_since_the_price_was_set,_the_probability_that_it_will_survive_i_''more''_periods_is_given_by_exactly_the_same_geometric_distribution_for_all_i=1,\dotsc,\infty._Thus_if_''h''_=_0.25,_then_however_old_the_price_is,_it_is_expected_to_last_another_4_periods.


_Calvo_pricing_and_nominal_rigidity

With_the_Calvo_model_the_response_of_prices_to_a_shock_is_spread_out_over_time._Suppose_a_shock_hits_the_economy_at_time_''t''._A_proportion_''h''_of_prices_can_respond_immediately_and_the_rest_''(1-h)''_remain_fixed._The_next_period,_there_will_still_be__(1-h)^_who_have_remained_fixed_and_not_responded_to_the_shock._i_periods_after_the_shock_this_which_have_shrunk_to_(1-h)^.__After_any_finite_time,_there_will_still_be_some_proportion_of_prices_that_have_not_responded_and_remained_fixed.__This_contrasts_with_the_Taylor_Contracts_(economics).html" ;"title=".html" ;"title="mathrm[i">mathrm[i=h^. For example, if the Calvo probability ''h'' is 0.25 per period, the expected duration is 4 periods. Since the Calvo probability is constant and does not depend on how long it has been since the price was set, the probability that it will survive i ''more'' periods is given by exactly the same geometric distribution for all i=1,\dotsc,\infty. Thus if ''h'' = 0.25, then however old the price is, it is expected to last another 4 periods.


Calvo pricing and nominal rigidity

With the Calvo model the response of prices to a shock is spread out over time. Suppose a shock hits the economy at time ''t''. A proportion ''h'' of prices can respond immediately and the rest ''(1-h)'' remain fixed. The next period, there will still be (1-h)^ who have remained fixed and not responded to the shock. i periods after the shock this which have shrunk to (1-h)^. After any finite time, there will still be some proportion of prices that have not responded and remained fixed. This contrasts with the Taylor Contracts (economics)">Taylor model, where there is a fixed length for contracts - for example 4 periods. After 4 periods, firms will have reset their price. The Calvo pricing model played a key role in the derivation of the New Keynesian Phillips curve by John Roberts in 1995, and since been used in New Keynesian DSGE models. :\pi_ = \beta E_[\pi_] + \kappa y_ \qquad \mbox where :\kappa = \frac\gamma. The current expectations of next period's inflation are incorporated as \beta E_
pi_ The number (; spelled out as "pi") is a mathematical constant that is the ratio of a circle's circumference to its diameter, approximately equal to 3.14159. The number appears in many formulas across mathematics and physics. It is an irratio ...
/math>. The coefficient \kappa captures the responsiveness of current inflation to current output. The New Keynesian Phillips curve reflects the fact that price-setting is forward looking, and what influences current inflation is not only the level of current demand (as represented by output) but also expected future inflation. There are different ways of measuring nominal rigidity in an economy. There will be many firms (or price-setters), some tend to change price frequently, others less so. Even a firm which changes its "normal" price infrequently might make a special offer or sale for a short period before returning to its normal price. Two possible ways of measuring nominal rigidity that have been suggested are: (i) The average age of contracts. One can take all of the firms and ask how long the prices have been set at their current level. With Calvo price setting, assuming that all firms have the same hazard rate ''h'', there will be a proportion h which have just been reset, a proportion ''h.(1-h)'' which reset in the previous period and remain fixed this period, and in general, the proportion of prices set i periods ago that survive today is given by \alpha^, where: :\alpha^=(1-h)^h The average age of contracts A^* is then :A^*= \sum_^i h^i(1-h)^ = \frac The average age of contracts is one measure of nominal rigidity. However, it suffers from interruption bias: at any point of time, we will only observe how long a price has been at its current level. We might wish to ask what will its completed length be at the next price change. This is the second measure. (ii) The average completed length of contracts. This is similar to the average age in that it looks at the current prices set by firms. However, rather than asking how long was it since the price was last set (the age of the contract), it asks how long will the price have lasted when the price next changes. Clearly for a single firm, this is random. Across all firms, however, the Law of large numbers kicks in and we can calculate the exact distribution of completed contract lengths. It can be shown that the average completed length of contracts is given by T: :T=\frac - 1 = 2A^-1 That is, the completed length of contracts is twice the average age minus 1. Thus, for example, if ''h''= 0.25, 25% of prices change each period. At any time, the average age of prices will be 4 periods. However, the corresponding average completed length of contracts is 7 periods.


Development of the concept

One of the major problems with the Calvo contract as a model of pricing is that the inflation dynamics it results in do not fit the data. Inflation is better described by the hybrid new Keyensian Phillips curve which includes lagged inflation: :\pi_ = (1-\psi)\beta E_
pi_ The number (; spelled out as "pi") is a mathematical constant that is the ratio of a circle's circumference to its diameter, approximately equal to 3.14159. The number appears in many formulas across mathematics and physics. It is an irratio ...
\psi\pi_ + \kappa y_ \qquad \mbox This has led to the original Calvo model to be developed in a number of directions: (a) Indexation. With
indexation Indexation is a technique to adjust income payments by means of a price index, in order to maintain the purchasing power of the public after inflation, while deindexation is the unwinding of indexation. Overview From a macroeconomics standpoin ...
, prices are automatically updated in response to lagged inflation (at least to some degree), which gives rise to the hybrid new Keyensian Phillips curve. The Calvo probability refers to the firm being able to choose the price it sets that period (which happens with probability h) or to have the price rise by indexation (which happens with probability (1-h). The Calvo model with indexation is adopted by many new Keynesian researchers (b) Duration dependent hazard function h(i). A key feature of the Calvo model is that the hazard rate is constant: the probability of changing the price does not depend on how old the price is. In 1999, Wolman suggested that the model should be generalized to allow for the hazard rate to vary with the duration. The key idea is that an older price may be more or less likely to change than a newer price, which is captured by the hazard function ''h(i)'' which allows the hazard rate to be a function of age i. This ''generalized Calvo model'' with duration dependent hazard rate has been developed by several authors.Sheedy, Kevin (2010), ''Intrinsic inflation persistence'',
Journal of Monetary Economics The ''Journal of Monetary Economics'' is a peer-reviewed academic journal covering research on macroeconomics and monetary economics. It is published by Elsevier and was established in October 1973 by Karl Brunner and Charles I. Plosser. Beginn ...
, volume 57, pages 1049-1061


See also

* Taylor contract (economics)


References


Sources

*
David Romer David Hibbard Romer (born March 13, 1958) is an American economist, the Herman Royer Professor of Political Economy at the University of California, Berkeley, and the author of a standard textbook in graduate macroeconomics as well as many influ ...
, ''Advanced Macroeconomics'', McGraw-Hill Higher Education; 4 edition (1 May 2011) . * Carl Walsh ''Monetary Theory and Policy'' (3rd edition), MIT Press 2010, . * Michael Woodford, ''Money Interest and Prices'', Princeton University Press, 2003, . {{Macroeconomics New Keynesian economics