CES Aggregate
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

Constant elasticity of substitution (CES), in economics, is a property of some production functions and utility functions. Several economists have featured in the topic and have contributed in the final finding of the constant. They include Tom McKenzie, John Hicks and Joan Robinson. The vital economic element of the measure is that it provided the producer a clear picture of how to move between different modes or types of production. Specifically, it arises in a particular type of aggregator function which combines two or more types of consumption goods, or two or more types of production inputs into an aggregate quantity. This aggregator function exhibits constant
elasticity of substitution Elasticity of substitution is the ratio of percentage change in capital-labour ratio with the percentage change in Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution. In a competitive market, it measures the percentage change in the two inputs used in respons ...
.


CES production function

Despite having several factors of production in substitutability, the most common are the forms of elasticity of substitution. On the contrary of restricting direct empirical evaluation, the constant Elasticity of Substitution are simple to use and hence are widely used. McFadden states that;
The constant E.S assumption is a restriction on the form of production possibilities, and one can characterize the class of production functions which have this property. This has been done by Arrow-Chenery-Minhas-Solow for the two-factor production case.
The CES production function is a neoclassical production function that displays constant
elasticity of substitution Elasticity of substitution is the ratio of percentage change in capital-labour ratio with the percentage change in Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution. In a competitive market, it measures the percentage change in the two inputs used in respons ...
. In other words, the production technology has a constant percentage change in factor (e.g.
labour Labour or labor may refer to: * Childbirth, the delivery of a baby * Labour (human activity), or work ** Manual labour, physical work ** Wage labour, a socioeconomic relationship between a worker and an employer ** Organized labour and the labour ...
and
capital Capital may refer to: Common uses * Capital city, a municipality of primary status ** List of national capital cities * Capital letter, an upper-case letter Economics and social sciences * Capital (economics), the durable produced goods used f ...
) proportions due to a percentage change in marginal rate of technical substitution. The two factor (capital, labor) CES production function introduced by Solow, and later made popular by
Arrow An arrow is a fin-stabilized projectile launched by a bow. A typical arrow usually consists of a long, stiff, straight shaft with a weighty (and usually sharp and pointed) arrowhead attached to the front end, multiple fin-like stabilizers c ...
, Chenery, Minhas, and Solow is: :Q = F\cdot \left(a \cdot K^\rho+(1-a) \cdot L^\rho\right)^ where * Q = Quantity of output * F = Factor productivity * a = Share parameter * K, L = Quantities of primary production factors (Capital and Labor) * \rho = = Substitution parameter * \sigma = =
Elasticity of substitution Elasticity of substitution is the ratio of percentage change in capital-labour ratio with the percentage change in Marginal Rate of Technical Substitution. In a competitive market, it measures the percentage change in the two inputs used in respons ...
* \upsilon = degree of homogeneity of the production function. Where \upsilon = 1 (Constant return to scale), \upsilon < 1 (Decreasing return to scale), \upsilon > 1 (Increasing return to scale). As its name suggests, the CES production function exhibits constant elasticity of substitution between capital and labor. Leontief, linear and Cobb–Douglas functions are special cases of the CES production function. That is, * If \rho approaches 1, we have a linear or perfect substitutes function; * If \rho approaches zero in the limit, we get the
Cobb–Douglas production function In economics and econometrics, the Cobb–Douglas production function is a particular functional form of the production function, widely used to represent the technological relationship between the amounts of two or more inputs (particularly phy ...
; * If \rho approaches negative infinity we get the Leontief or perfect complements production function. The general form of the CES production function, with ''n'' inputs, is: : Q = F \cdot \left sum_^n a_X_^\ \right where * Q = Quantity of output * F = Factor productivity * a_ = Share parameter of input i, \sum_^n a_ = 1 * X_i = Quantities of factors of production (i = 1,2...n) * s=\frac = Elasticity of substitution. Extending the CES (Solow) functional form to accommodate multiple factors of production creates some problems. However, there is no completely general way to do this. Uzawa showed the only possible n-factor production functions (n>2) with constant partial elasticities of substitution require either that all elasticities between pairs of factors be identical, or if any differ, these all must equal each other and all remaining elasticities must be unity. This is true for any production function. This means the use of the CES functional form for more than 2 factors will generally mean that there is not constant elasticity of substitution among all factors. Nested CES functions are commonly found in partial equilibrium and general equilibrium models. Different nests (levels) allow for the introduction of the appropriate elasticity of substitution.


CES utility function

The same CES functional form arises as a utility function in consumer theory. For example, if there exist n types of consumption goods x_i, then aggregate consumption X could be defined using the CES aggregator: : X = \left sum_^n a_^x_^\ \right. Here again, the coefficients a_i are share parameters, and s is the elasticity of substitution. Therefore, the consumption goods x_i are perfect substitutes when s approaches infinity and perfect complements when s approaches zero. In the case where s approaches one is again a limiting case where L'Hôpital's Rule applies. The CES aggregator is also sometimes called the ''Armington aggregator'', which was discussed by Armington (1969). CES utility functions are a special case of homothetic preferences. The following is an example of a CES utility function for two goods, x and y, with equal shares: :u(x,y) =(x^r + y^r)^. The expenditure function in this case is: :e(p_x,p_y,u) =(p_x^ + p_y^)^ \cdot u. The indirect utility function is its inverse: :v(p_x,p_y,I) =(p_x^ + p_y^)^ \cdot I. The demand functions are: :x(p_x,p_y,I) = \frac\cdot I, :y(p_x,p_y,I) = \frac\cdot I. A CES utility function is one of the cases considered by Dixit and
Stiglitz Joseph Eugene Stiglitz (; born February 9, 1943) is an American New Keynesian economist, a public policy analyst, and a full professor at Columbia University. He is a recipient of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (2001) and the Joh ...
(1977) in their study of optimal product diversity in a context of monopolistic competition. Note the difference between CES utility and
isoelastic utility In economics, the isoelastic function for utility, also known as the isoelastic utility function, or power utility function, is used to express utility in terms of consumption or some other economic variable that a decision-maker is concerned with ...
: the CES utility function is an ordinal utility function that represents preferences on sure consumption commodity bundles, while the isoelastic utility function is a
cardinal utility In economics, a cardinal utility function or scale is a utility index that preserves preference orderings uniquely up to positive affine transformations. Two utility indices are related by an affine transformation if for the value u(x_i) of one ind ...
function that represents preferences on lotteries. A CES indirect (dual) utility function has been used to derive utility-consistent brand demand systems where category demands are determined endogenously by a multi-category, CES indirect (dual) utility function. It has also been shown that CES preferences are self-dual and that both primal and dual CES preferences yield systems of indifference curves that may exhibit any degree of convexity.


References

{{reflist


External links


Anatomy of CES Type Production Functions in 3DClosed form solution for a firm with an N-dimensional CES technologyMonopolists revenue function
Production economics Econometric modeling Elasticity (economics) Utility function types