Blackwell's Contraction Mapping Theorem
   HOME

TheInfoList



OR:

In mathematics, Blackwell's contraction mapping theorem provides a set of sufficient conditions for an operator to be a
contraction mapping In mathematics, a contraction mapping, or contraction or contractor, on a metric space (''M'', ''d'') is a function ''f'' from ''M'' to itself, with the property that there is some real number 0 \leq k < 1 such that for all ''x'' and ...
. It is widely used in areas that rely on dynamic programming as it facilitates the proof of existence of fixed points. The result is due to
David Blackwell David Harold Blackwell (April 24, 1919 – July 8, 2010) was an American statistician and mathematician who made significant contributions to game theory, probability theory, information theory, and statistics. He is one of the eponyms of the ...
who published it in 1965 in the
Annals of Mathematical Statistics The ''Annals of Mathematical Statistics'' was a peer-reviewed statistics journal published by the Institute of Mathematical Statistics from 1930 to 1972. It was superseded by the '' Annals of Statistics'' and the '' Annals of Probability''. In 1 ...
.


Statement of the Theorem

Let T be an operator defined over an ordered normed vector space X. T: X \rightarrow X is a contraction mapping with modulus \beta if it satisfies # (monotonicity) \quad u \leq v \implies Tu \leq Tv # (discounting) \quad T(u+c) \leq Tu+\beta c.


Proof of the Theorem

For all u and v \in X, u \leq v + , , v-u, , . Properties 1. and 2. imply that T(v) \leq T(u + , , v-u, , ) \leq T(u) + \beta , , v-u, , , hence, T(v)-T(u) \leq \beta , , v-u, , . Therefore , , T(v)-T(u), , \leq \beta , , v-u, , and T is a
contraction mapping In mathematics, a contraction mapping, or contraction or contractor, on a metric space (''M'', ''d'') is a function ''f'' from ''M'' to itself, with the property that there is some real number 0 \leq k < 1 such that for all ''x'' and ...
.


Illustration

If X is the real line with the usual order structure and T: X \rightarrow X is a differentiable map satisfying 0 \leq T'(x) \leq \beta <1 , then T satisfies the assumption because T'(x) >0 is equivalent to monotonicity and because the derivative assumption implies with the fundamental theorem of calculus that the discounting assumption T(u+c) =T(u) + \int_0^c T'(t) \; dt \leq \int_0^c \beta \; dt = Tu+\beta c holds. The conclusion of the Blackwell's contraction mapping theorem is that T is a contraction. While this is not an impressive conclusion in the context of calculus, it is notable that the theorem does not make any differentiability assumption. The discounting assumption however implies that T is Lipschitz continuous.


Applications


The cake eating problem

An agent has access to only one cake for its entire, infinite, life. It has to decide the optimal way to consume it. It evaluates a consumption plan, c_t, by using a separable utility function, \sum_^ \beta^t \frac, with discounting factor \beta \in (0,1). Its problem can be summarized as \max_\sum_^ \beta^t \frac \text x_t = x_ - c_t \text x_=0 \textc_t\geq0 \text x_t \geq 0 \, \forall \, t \, \in \, \mathbb_+ . () Applying Bellman's principle of optimality we find ()'s corresponding
Bellman equation A Bellman equation, named after Richard E. Bellman, is a necessary condition for optimality associated with the mathematical Optimization (mathematics), optimization method known as dynamic programming. It writes the "value" of a decision problem ...
V(c) = \max_ \frac + \beta V(c') . () It can be proven that the solution to this functional equation, if it exists, is equivalent to the solution of ().Stokey, Nancy L., Robert E. Lucas, and Edward C. Prescott. Recursive Methods in Economic Dynamics. Harvard University Press, 1989. https://doi.org/10.2307/j.ctvjnrt76. To prove its existence we can resort to Blackwell's sufficient conditions. Define the operator T(V(c)) = \max_ \frac + \beta V(c') . A solution to () is equivalent to finding a fixed-point for our operator. If we prove that this operator is a contraction mapping then we can use Banach's fixed-point theorem, and conclude that there is indeed a solution to (). First note that T is defined over the space of bounded functions since for all feasible consumption plans, \sum_^ \beta^t \frac \leq \sum_^ \beta^t \frac = \frac < \infty. Endowing it with the sup-norm we conclude that the domain and co-domain are ordered normed vector spaces. We are just left with verifying that the conditions for Blackwell's theorem are respected: #(monotonicity) \textV(c) \geq U(c) \, \forall \, c \, \in \, ,1/math> then T(V(c)) = \max_ \frac + \beta V(c') \geq \max_ \frac + \beta U(c') = T(U(c)) #(discounting) T(V(c)+a) = \max_ \frac + \beta (V(c') + a) \leq \max_ \frac + \beta V(c') + \beta a = T(V(c)) + \beta a where a is a constant function.


References

{{reflist Fixed-point theorems Metric geometry Linear operators