Bertrand competition is a model of competition used in economics, named after
Joseph Louis François Bertrand
Joseph Louis François Bertrand (; 11 March 1822 – 5 April 1900) was a French mathematician who worked in the fields of number theory, differential geometry, probability theory, economics and thermodynamics.
Biography
Joseph Bertrand was the ...
(1822–1900). It describes interactions among firms (sellers) that set prices and their customers (buyers) that choose quantities at the prices set. The model was formulated in 1883 by Bertrand in a review of
Antoine Augustin Cournot's book ''Recherches sur les Principes Mathématiques de la Théorie des Richesses'' (1838) in which Cournot had put forward the
Cournot model Cournot competition is an economic model used to describe an industry structure in which companies compete on the amount of output they will produce, which they decide on independently of each other and at the same time. It is named after Antoine Au ...
. Cournot's model argued that each firm should maximise its profit by selecting a quantity level and then adjusting price level to sell that quantity. The outcome of the model equilibrium involved firms pricing above marginal cost; hence, the competitive price. In his review, Bertrand argued that each firm should instead maximise its profits by selecting a price level that undercuts its competitors' prices, when their prices exceed marginal cost.
The model was not formalized by Bertrand; however, the idea was developed into a mathematical model by
Francis Ysidro Edgeworth
Francis Ysidro Edgeworth (8 February 1845 – 13 February 1926) was an Anglo-Irish philosopher and political economist who made significant contributions to the methods of statistics during the 1880s. From 1891 onward, he was appointed th ...
in 1889.
Underlying assumptions of Bertrand competition
Considering the simple framework, the underlying assumptions that the Bertrand model makes is as follows:
* there are
firms (
) competing in the market that produce homogenous goods; that is, identical products;
* the market demand function
, where ''Q'' is the summation of quantity produced by firms
, is continuous and downward sloping with
'';''
* the
marginal cost
In economics, the marginal cost is the change in the total cost that arises when the quantity produced is incremented, the cost of producing additional quantity. In some contexts, it refers to an increment of one unit of output, and in others it r ...
is symmetric,
'';''
* it is a static game; firms simultaneously set price, without knowing the other firm’s decision;
and
* firms don't have a capacity constraint; that is, each firm has the capability to produce enough goods to meet market demand.
Furthermore, it is intuitively deducible, when considering the law of demand of firms' competition in the market:
* the firm that sets the lowest price will acquire the whole the market; since, product is homogenous and there is no cost of switching for the customers;
and
* if the price set by the firms is the same,
'','' they will serve the market equally,
.
The Bertrand duopoly equilibrium
Why is the competitive price a
Nash equilibrium
In game theory, the Nash equilibrium, named after the mathematician John Nash, is the most common way to define the solution of a non-cooperative game involving two or more players. In a Nash equilibrium, each player is assumed to know the equili ...
in the Bertrand model? First, if both firms set the competitive price with price equal to marginal cost (unit cost), neither firm will earn any profits. However, if one firm sets price equal to marginal cost, then if the other firm raises its price above unit cost, then it will earn nothing, since all consumers will buy from the firm still setting the competitive price (recall that it is willing to meet unlimited demand at price equals unit cost even though it earns no profit). No other price is an equilibrium. If both firms set the same price above unit cost and share the market, then each firm has an incentive to undercut the other by an arbitrarily small amount and capture the whole market and almost double its profits. So there can be no equilibrium with both firms setting the same price above marginal cost. This is due to the firms competing over goods and services that are considered substitutes; that is, consumers having identical preferences towards each product and only preferring the cheaper of the two. Also, there can be no equilibrium with firms setting different prices. The firms setting the higher price will earn nothing (the lower priced firm serves all of the customers). Hence the higher priced firm will want to lower its price to undercut the lower-priced firm. Hence the ''only'' equilibrium in the Bertrand model occurs when both firms set price equal to unit cost (the competitive price).
Note that the Bertrand equilibrium is a ''weak'' Nash-equilibrium. The firms lose nothing by deviating from the competitive price: it is an equilibrium simply because each firm can earn no more than zero profits given that the other firm sets the competitive price and is willing to meet all demand at that price.
Classic modelling of the Bertrand competition
The Bertrand model of price competition in a duopoly market producing homogenous goods has the following characteristics:
* Players: Two firms
with constant marginal cost
;
* Strategic Variables: Firm’s select the price level (i.e.,
);
* Timing: Simultaneous move game;
* Firm Payoffs: Profit; and
* Information: Complete.
Firm
’s individual demand function is downward sloping and a function of the price set by each firm: